Discover millions of ebooks, audiobooks, and so much more with a free trial

Only $11.99/month after trial. Cancel anytime.

After the Storm: The World Economy and Britain's Economic Future
After the Storm: The World Economy and Britain's Economic Future
After the Storm: The World Economy and Britain's Economic Future
Ebook440 pages6 hours

After the Storm: The World Economy and Britain's Economic Future

Rating: 0 out of 5 stars

()

Read preview

About this ebook

From the bestselling author of The Storm comes a fascinating insight into the state of the British economy from one of our leading politicians, who was at the heart of the coalition government. Vince Cable's bestselling book, The Storm, explored and explained the causes of the 2008 world economic crisis and how Britain should respond to the great challenges it brought. In After the Storm, Cable, who was Business Secretary in the 2010-2015 coalition government, provides a unique perspective on the state of the global financial markets and how the British economy has fared since 2008. Providing a previously unreported inside view of the Coalition, After the Storm offers a carefully considered perspective on how the British economy should be managed over the next decade and beyond. This timely book is a fascinating and urgent intervention from one of the key figures in British politics of the past two decades.
LanguageEnglish
Release dateSep 17, 2015
ISBN9781782394518
After the Storm: The World Economy and Britain's Economic Future

Read more from Vince Cable

Related to After the Storm

Related ebooks

Finance & Money Management For You

View More

Related articles

Reviews for After the Storm

Rating: 0 out of 5 stars
0 ratings

0 ratings0 reviews

What did you think?

Tap to rate

Review must be at least 10 words

    Book preview

    After the Storm - Vince Cable

    After the Storm:

    The World Economy &

    Britain’s Economic Future

    Also by Vince Cable

    Free Radical

    The Storm

    First published in Great Britain in 2015 by Atlantic Books, an imprint of Atlantic Books Ltd.

    Copyright © Vince Cable, 2015

    The moral right of Vince Cable to be identified as the author of this work has been asserted by him in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act of 1988.

    All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise, without the prior permission of both the copyright owner and the above publisher of this book.

    The picture and graph acknowledgements on p. 303–16 constitute an extension of this copyright page.

    Every effort has been made to trace or contact all copyright holders. The publishers will be pleased to make good any omissions or rectify any mistakes brought to their attention at the earliest opportunity.

    10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1

    A CIP catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library.

    Hardback ISBN: 978 178 239449 5

    E-book ISBN: 978 178 239451 8

    Printed in Great Britain

    Atlantic Books

    An Imprint of Atlantic Books Ltd

    Ormond House

    26–27 Boswell Street

    London

    WC1N 3JZ

    www.atlantic-books.co.uk

    Contents

    Introduction

    I embarked on this book as a sequel to The Storm, which was my attempt to explain the 2008 financial crisis and its aftermath. The Storm was by no means the most eloquent, insightful or profound analysis of the crisis, but it had the merit of being one of the first to hit the bookshops.

    One motivation for writing this sequel is to update the arguments and review the evidence at the current, awkward juncture, when there is a sense of relief that the crisis has seemingly passed and economic recovery is taking place, but also a continuing worry that there are deep-seated problems at home and abroad that haven’t yet been satisfactorily resolved.

    A further motivation derives from the fact that I have spent five years not merely as an observer of the economy but as a senior member of the coalition government. My Cabinet responsibilities – for Business Innovation and Skills (BIS) and as President of the Board of Trade – put me at the heart of many of the debates around the economy, both within the coalition and outside it. Those debates broke surface mainly in the form of sound-bites, or leaks, or heavily spun comments. I felt it would be useful to describe the issues in a more coherent and transparent way.

    For these reasons, I embarked on this book in the latter stages of my period as secretary of state. In the event, the rules surrounding the propriety of ministers’ publishing activities prevented its completion. The ending of my parliamentary and ministerial career was brutally sudden, but has liberated me to return to the text without the previous inhibitions of collective responsibility.

    The election campaign reinforced my determination to publish. At a very general level, the campaign had an economic thread: in most parts of the country there was a collective judgement that the coalition had been broadly successful in securing recovery, and that this should not be put at risk by allowing in what was successfully portrayed by the Conservatives as a destabilizing left-wing alternative of Labour and the SNP. One personally painful consequence was that even those of us who had contributed substantially to the economic recovery were swept away. I have described elsewhere (New Statesman, 22–28 May 2015) how the Conservatives’ ruthlessly effective deployment of the ‘politics of fear’, combined with disillusionment with the coalition among left-leaning voters, squeezed my party’s support to disastrous levels.

    However, aside from the broadest generalities, the economic debate around the election was beyond abysmal. Except at a few, niche hustings meetings there was no discussion whatever of the key question of how we should raise productivity levels and living standards. Austerity was discussed as if it were some self-imposed, masochistic fetish enjoyed by some and hated by others – an economic version of Fifty Shades of Grey. Crucially important issues like housing were addressed by policies (‘Help to Buy’ and the further discounted ‘Right to Buy’) so cynically populist that they seemed calculated to make a bad problem worse by boosting house price inflation. More generally, ‘Abroad’ was largely wished away – except in the context of immigration. As was the future, which gained far less attention than the attribution of historic economic guilt, about which the Conservatives were obsessed. As a parliamentarian for eighteen years, and a Cabinet minister for five years, I am far from being a politically innocent policy wonk, but I do believe that economic policy should be debated more seriously.

    The election also exposed a deeper and more alarming undercurrent, as the issues of Scotland, immigration and Europe generated an emotional reaction more powerful than the traditional class-based tribalism of British party politics. Twenty years ago I wrote one of two pamphlets for the think-tank Demos about the emerging ‘politics of identity’. It described how people were either developing ‘multiple identities’ in response to growing globalization, or were retreating into political or wider social movements built on race, religion, language or national identity. At the time, the pattern fitted the collapsing autocracies of the USSR and Eastern Europe better than the mature Western democracies. Although I anticipated a similar shift in the UK, I scarcely imagined that in my suburban London constituency, as well as in Scotland, the battles of Bannockburn and Culloden would be refought in people’s minds. The practical consequence of the politics of identity is that, for years to come, British politics will be dominated by the future of the Union, by debate about our continued membership of the European Union, and by the perceived threat of Islam. For a country like ours, which defines itself by its self-confident openness to ideas and commerce, the dangers of a revival of nationalism and the fear of others are especially acute.

    My approach to these problems and to this book, my assumptions and prejudices, are governed by my own experience. I was taught, and have taught, the standard macroeconomics and microeconomics applying to the UK and other developed economies. I was a disciple of both Adam Smith and John Maynard Keynes, liberals both. But until becoming an MP in my mid-fifties, I had done no serious work on the UK economy beyond pamphleteering on free trade, liberal immigration, Britain’s membership of an open European Union and, somewhat ahead of its time, Scottish home rule. My experience of UK national policy-making was confined to a brief interlude in the diplomatic service and an even briefer period as John Smith’s special adviser at the sad, decaying end of the Callaghan government, at the Department of Trade – episodes I described in an earlier book, Free Radical.

    My passion and economic expertise had primarily been in the field of development: trying to understand what turns poor countries into rich(er) ones. I have seen theories of economic growth brought alive as poor countries have adapted and used technological progress rapidly to transform previously agrarian, peasant economies. My professional (and personal) life is framed by my fifty years’ experience of India: as a travelling student seeing a vast sea of poverty and hunger, with some islands of urban commerce and state-controlled industry; and as a British minister, promoting trade and investment and negotiating with what had become the world’s third largest economy, and working with Britain’s biggest manufacturing company, now Indian-owned. The rapid emergence of China and India from centuries of mass destitution is the big economic story of our time and, generally, a positive one. This background helped to frame the main question I asked as a minister: how, in such a world, does a middle-sized and relatively declining country like Britain earn a living?

    Immersion in issues of development also opened my eyes to latent threats. I saw how easily financial markets can spin out of control. Working with Lord Lever and others on the Latin American debt crisis introduced me to the collective stupidity and greed of bankers, three decades before our own financial crash, and made me aware of the harm they can do.

    Subsequent years with Shell taught me not only about the perspective of a major global company but also about the importance of the long view: looking beyond the immediate and urgent to the enduring and important. As part of the company’s scenario planning team, then as chief economist, I was part of a group that envisaged two decades ago the world we have today, but that seemed implausible then. This was what we called New Frontiers: where growth at a global level was increasingly driven and dominated by emerging markets, the former developing and communist economies; where the business landscape would be totally transformed by technologies largely unknown at the time and companies no one had heard of, mostly originating in the USA; where insecurity and inequality would intensify. In the company’s approach to planning and strategy, nothing could have been further removed from the parochialism and short-term perspectives that dominate British political discussion today – even though as a minister I tried to swim against that tide.

    From that world I moved into the House of Commons as a Lib Dem MP in 1997. I found satisfaction as an assiduous local MP, and I found a policy niche delving into the seemingly endless mis-selling scandals of the financial services sector, including trying to arrest the decline of mutual ownership and campaigning on behalf of small savers. By the mid-2000s the British economy was coasting along comfortably after a decade of uninterrupted growth, combined with low inflation, reinforced by an independent central bank. There was a palpable sense of material well-being and optimism, reflected in the 2005 general election, that the country had found, in the Blair–Brown era, a good blend of apparently successful business expansion and social democratic fairness, manifested in the minimum wage, in-work tax credits and moderately redistributive taxation. The only sour note was provided by the Iraq War.

    For an opposition economic spokesman (I was the Lib Dem shadow Chancellor at the time) there were slim pickings and quite a lot to admire. There was a broad consensus on the fundamentals of domestic economic management and an open economy (including a liberal approach to immigration).

    Nevertheless, I worried increasingly that something was wrong. Growth was being sustained, not by strong investment, innovation and exports, but by consumption that, in turn, depended in significant part on household borrowing, including equity release from rapidly appreciating house prices. The price of housing escalated to new peaks, both in absolute terms and in relation to income, and was supported by bank lending at what appeared to be dangerously implausible multiples of borrowers’ income and property values. I was critical of the banks – like Northern Rock and HBOS – that appeared to be pouring paraffin on a fire already in danger of getting out of control, and of the government (especially the Treasury) and the Bank of England for ignoring the issue. There was, reflecting the same underlying imbalance in the economy, a serious relative decline in manufacturing, continuing a trend from the Thatcher era. That was offset by a boom in financial services, notably banking, liberated by the deregulation of the late 1980s. And the exchange rate was seriously overvalued in real terms. The Conservatives developed independently a critique of this period of government, based on excessive growth of government spending – which had an element of truth, but was much the lesser problem.

    I have subsequently been credited by some with having predicted the world financial crisis. Flattering, but wrong. I didn’t. But I did correctly say how and why the British boom would go bust, and I advanced the then heretical thought that the banking system was becoming dangerously large and unstable. As acting and then deputy leader of my party, I had a ready-made platform when the collapse occurred. I learned, to my advantage, the force of the old adage that in the kingdom of the blind, the one-eyed man is king. I was also fortunate, as an economist, to belong to an older generation that had been taught about the principles of banking, before the subject was discarded as being of no great interest, and to have been taught by the disciples of Keynes, rather than by later, deluded believers in ‘efficient’ financial markets. But there was much that I did not understand as the crisis unfolded, and I sat down to write The Storm in order to clarify my own thinking – and, perhaps, to help others in the process.

    Even after five years in government, I sensed that we were still trapped in the narrative of five years earlier. Who was to blame for the financial crisis and the subsequent recession? Was austerity, in the form of budget deficit reduction, premature and excessive? These old arguments obscured more important and interesting, forward-looking questions. How serious are the domestic and overseas risks to recovery? How should residual fiscal deficit reduction objectives best be secured with the least economic, and social, damage? Is the banking system now secure? How can short-term recovery be translated into long-term sustainable and balanced growth? The backward-looking arguments matter, however, since whoever owns them has legitimacy and the crucial advantage of a reputation for competence.

    There are aspects of that history that reverberate to this day. Was the coalition really necessary? What persuaded my party to take the risk of losing its identity as a minority party in a tie-up with its traditional political foes? And what persuaded the Conservatives to abandon a long antipathy to coalition, and to ourselves? There is now a broad understanding, even among the coalition government’s critics, that the arithmetic of the 2010 election created its own logic, with no other combination of parties capable of forming a stable government. The story of how the coalition was formed has been described in detail elsewhere. As my party’s deputy leader and shadow Chancellor, obviously I had a heavy responsibility. Whatever my personal aversion to working with the Conservatives, I could see no alternative.

    During the negotiations, I had several approaches from Gordon Brown, exploring the alternative of a centre-left coalition. He was aware, as much as anyone, of the dangers posed by international financial turbulence, and he wanted a strong government that could take a leadership role in Europe, continuing the work he had done to help stabilize the world economy two years earlier. I personally had – and have – a high regard and liking for Gordon Brown, and I believe the history books will be kinder to him than contemporary judgements. But it was clear, despite his own commitment to making a coalition work, that the parliamentary arithmetic was not there. I am sure it was true, too, that the Cameron–Clegg talks were too well advanced by that stage, and that Gordon Brown’s wish to continue was regarded by my colleagues as an obstacle, rather than an alternative. In any event, the precariousness of the country’s economic position meant that there was a sense of urgency about creating an agreed, substantial plan of action, rather than a temporary sticking-plaster solution. What is perhaps not so readily understood, by a public inclined to believe that all politicians are thieves and knaves, is that my party colleagues and I believed we were doing the right thing for the country.

    The sense of urgency and importance was enhanced by the personal briefings I received by phone during the coalition negotiations from the Cabinet Secretary and the permanent secretary to the Treasury, reflecting, at one remove, the views of the Governor of the Bank of England. The formation of the coalition coincided with the first major crisis of confidence in Greek government bonds and the euro. The government’s top officials expressed the fear that, as the country most exposed to the banking crisis and with the largest fiscal deficit of any major country, the ‘contagion’ could easily spread to the UK. Since the UK had – and has – its own currency, which can float, the fear was not of a classic currency crisis, but that it would be difficult to sell British government debt, which would drive down the price of bonds and drive up their yield – that is, drive up the cost of borrowing. While they were speaking, quite properly, within civil service constraints, they made it clear that the politicians had a key role: to establish confidence, and that required a stable government with a commitment to improve the public finances.

    There was little disagreement then, or during the early stages of the coalition government, over the necessity for such action. At that stage, there was a broad understanding among all three parties that spending cuts and tax rises were inevitable – though there was a marked absence of specifics. I had written a pamphlet nine months earlier detailing a programme of consolidation, setting out some difficult possible spending cuts, and proposing a schedule close to that later adopted by the coalition. It was badly received at my party conference in Bournemouth in September 2009, by colleagues who felt that my talk of cuts was premature and unhelpful. I was asked to appear at a meeting of an anxious and angry parliamentary party during the conference to explain why I thought public spending would have to be cut. The view prevailed (and not only among the Lib Dems) that talk of cuts repelled voters, while spending commitments attracted them, and this led us into the disaster of the tuition fees pledge, among others. Even the Conservatives, anxious to appear as the leading fiscal hawks, had said little beyond the need for ‘efficiency savings’ and ‘tackling waste’, and one of their main commitments – hailed by much of the press as a political masterstroke – was a promise to cut inheritance tax. But whichever party was in government would have faced the need for difficult, unpopular cuts and tax rises.

    The new element, introduced by the eurozone drama and agreed during the subsequent coalition negotiations, was a Conservative-led commitment to bring forward a first round of £11 billion of fiscal consolidation. Much was made of this change of emphasis by the Lib Dems at the time, but it seemed a sensible, and modest, response to what was happening in the real world. The fact that, five years later, the coalition government had reached roughly the mid-point in its programme of fiscal consolidation is eloquent testimony to the flexibility that was employed in practice, and also to the practical difficulties of proceeding any faster. Despite the sound and fury around fiscal policy – the austerity debate – I do not believe that any plausible government would have pursued radically different policies or achieved a radically different outcome. The outgoing Labour government had, in fact, already initiated cuts, as I discovered when I entered ministerial office, in areas such as further education. Moreover, by launching the Browne review of university tuition fees, it was preparing the ground for unpopular decisions that the next government would have to take.

    The more potent and lingering disagreement has been over who was to blame for the financial crisis and the legacy of budget deficits. The search for the ‘guilty men’ was, explicitly or implicitly, a theme of almost every speech during the 2015 election campaign – and, I suspect, will reverberate for a generation to come. For the Conservatives, it was crucial to establish that the crisis was caused by a fiscally incontinent Labour government that spent too much, rather than by the financial markets which they had let off the leash under Thatcher, and where they retained close and lucrative relationships with party donors. This political battle the Conservatives won hands-down, despite there being only weak evidence to support their argument. A combination of Tory triumphalism and Labour embarrassment has led to a rewriting of history. As I show in chapter seven, the fiscal position before 2008 was heading in the wrong direction but was basically sound and better than that which Labour had inherited in 1997.

    For the angry populist fringes of left or right, however, the crisis was a failure of a corrupt, complacent ruling class of politicians who had allowed greedy bankers to run amok and then escape, and who were abetted by a variety of other pantomime villains in Brussels and multinational companies. The populist fringes made only limited inroads in the 2015 election (outside Scotland, where there has been a different dynamic). But the coming European referendum will be a fertile recruiting ground for them.

    In The Storm I argued that there was no politically convenient, simple explanation for what happened during the crisis. Responsibility was widely spread. We have been suffering from the prolonged after-effects of a massive banking crisis which was global in character, but which struck the UK particularly hard because of the scale of the UK banking sector. For that, the excesses of the banking industry and poor supervision of it were largely to blame. The Labour government can reasonably be criticized for being asleep at the wheel and failing to spot the warning signs of an uncontrolled credit and housing boom and an inflated banking sector, and for reacting too late. But when disaster struck, the government and the Bank of England, along with the US authorities, dealt with the consequences in a commendably rational way. The large fiscal hole inherited by the coalition government was mainly the consequence of the financial crisis itself, rather than a previous history of structural deficits, which were real but small.

    However unfairly, the Conservatives have won the political argument about historic responsibility, and they had the support of the coalition to take difficult decisions after 2010. But in future, their approach to dealing with the residual fiscal legacy may be judged more harshly since, beyond the rhetoric about a ‘long-term economic plan’ and ‘financial responsibility’, the public has not been properly prepared for the cuts they plan. The proposed £12 billion in welfare cuts, for example, appears to have been formulated without much forethought and on the basis that the Liberal Democrats would be around to dilute them. It was clear from the July 2015 budget that much of the bill would be paid by low-income families in work, contrary to earlier commitments to make work pay.

    After five years in government, there is a lot to be written about who said what to whom and when. There will come a time when diaries are published and the life of the coalition is told in full. I was involved in some of the high-profile dramas of the government – around the Murdochs and Leveson, the scale of spending cuts, the Lib Dems’ tuition fees disaster, clashes over immigration and Europe – and more peripherally in others. But some readers may be disappointed at the lack of spice and narrative detail – the absence of gossip and tales of personality clashes – since I will use the discussion of my time in government primarily as a backdrop to considering the economy, past and future.

    It may come as a surprise to many that the government worked much more smoothly and that relations were much better than the daily reports of rows, feuds, splits, leaks and plots would suggest. What the public actually sees is somewhat like professional wrestling: a confusing mixture of play-acting and genuine combat. For the most part, my experience of coalition government was that, when it mattered, it was professional and surprisingly collegiate. Civil servants often observed that the coalition worked better than the Labour government since, while we often disagreed about issues, personalities were not allowed to get in the way of resolving them. Messrs Cameron and Clegg deserve credit for that. And in my own corner of government, sometimes portrayed in the press as an ideological battleground between a grumpy, left-wing secretary of state and various true-blue Tory ministers, relations were always business-like and often cordial. In some cases, as with the universities minister, David Willetts, there was a real sense of partnership. I took the view from the outset that we should leave our weapons at the door and work as a team. Our shifting cast, of two Lib Dems and up to six full-time or shared Tory ministers, with a small team of special advisers to broker agreements, largely functioned in this cooperative way, though I was conscious that my Tory colleagues were regularly being warned of the dangers of going native by their controllers in No. 10 and No. 11. Towards the end there were spats about who should claim the credit for various achievements, though I take satisfaction from the fact that there were achievements to fight over, rather than disasters for which to apportion blame.

    My own approach to coalition, and to my BIS colleagues, was a mixture of defence and offence. Some things had to be stopped, others had to be done. I and my Lib Dem colleagues wanted progressive reforms, which we had to barter for things the Tories wanted. I sought to block what I regarded as ideologically driven spending cuts, beyond what had been agreed as being necessary for fiscal stability. For example, there was a long hiatus after the breakdown of negotiations on 2015/16 spending, when demands from the Treasury would have done serious harm to vocational education outside the universities. Indeed, I carried out a five-year rearguard action to prevent high-flying Treasury graduates demolishing adult and further education, which they neither understood nor respected. I did block ‘hire and fire’ labour-market legislation as recommended in the Beecroft Report, and attempts by the Chancellor to set a high minimum wage as part of a bidding war with Labour, as well as the more extreme proposals to tighten immigration rules on overseas students and non-EU skilled workers, attempts to stop free speech in universities, and unnecessary and provocative reforms to trade unions. I also referred the News Corp–BSkyB takeover to the competition authorities, which helped ensure that it never happened. I see that the new Conservative government has quickly moved its tanks on to most of these, now unprotected, corners of the battlefield. Under the coalition, it was possible to mobilize my party leader when the Conservatives would not take ‘no’ for an answer, so as to weave particular disputes into the wider tapestry of the coalition agreement.

    Not all the disagreements were between the coalition parties. Although I had difficult exchanges with the Home Secretary and prime minister over immigration controls on non-EU students and skilled workers, almost all Conservative colleagues and ministers agreed, at least privately, that their policies were seriously damaging to business, universities and the wider national economic interest. As a Lib Dem, I was able to speak publicly about the way that the government’s claim to be ‘open for business’ was being undermined. But I was struck by the inability of powerful Conservatives like the Chancellor, or even the prime minister, to move the Home Secretary an inch.

    Most of the time and energy of my Lib Dem team of two, and my two special advisers, was devoted to finding common ground with the Conservatives and delivering positive results. These included the launching of an industrial strategy and the boosting of advanced manufacturing and creative industries; an unpopular but necessary overhaul of university and student finances, and liberalization of the sector; the resurrection and reform of apprenticeships; bank restructuring and ‘ring-fencing’, and the successful launch of the British Business Bank and the Green Investment Bank; corporate governance reform, including executive pay and a register of beneficial ownership; a chain of new, industry-led innovation centres, known as Catapults; shared parental leave and flexible working; better gender balance on company boards; introducing private and worker ownership of the Royal Mail, and rescuing the Post Office network; an overhaul of the competition regime and the Takeover Code; providing protection for supermarket suppliers and pubs from market abuse; expanding the role of adult education into mental health; copyright reform; and much else besides. Sometimes, an explicit deal was involved. I got the Chancellor’s backing for the British Business Bank in return for not opposing his controversial scheme to create a new form of worker ownership with fewer rights (on the assumption that it wouldn’t fly, as it didn’t). In short, the coalition was not a zero-sum game. It did many useful things, but usually at the price of a messy compromise.

    The dilemma for me as a Lib Dem secretary of state was that I could gain a distinctive identity for my party by opposing and blocking, or I could achieve results by gaining Tory acquiescence and support for my own proposals, which often meant risking losing ownership of the issue. A typical example was apprenticeships. In the tough bargaining around the 2010 spending round, I had managed to ease some of the political pain of increasing student tuition fees by channelling more resources into apprenticeships, which subsequently expanded rapidly. The Conservatives were quick to spot the appeal of the apprenticeship brand and never ceased to claim ownership of the policy. A similar fate awaited the Lib Dem commitment to raise income tax thresholds, which the Conservatives initially disdained. The battle for ownership was at the heart of the coalition, and we struggled as a party to gain the credit for popular policies that had originated with us, since we were numerically outgunned five to one across government.

    Whatever external impression may have been created, I was primarily interested in making things happen, rather than stopping things happen. Moreover, I had the benefit of some impressive and enthusiastic civil servants and a generally harmonious ministerial team. Whitehall gossip had it that BIS was one department where coalition worked, with genuine give and take. Others included Work and Pensions under Iain Duncan Smith (‘IDS’), Health under both Andrew Lansley and Jeremy Hunt, and Transport under Patrick McLoughlin. Others were notoriously factional. The experience of Nick Harvey at Defence and Norman Baker at the Home Office was altogether less happy. We also had to work across government, through Cabinet committees, as well as in Cabinet and in direct relationships with the prime minister and Chancellor. I was left with very ambivalent feelings. The Tories collectively could be appalling, with some ugly tribal prejudices, and when their party interests were directly challenged they could be vicious. During the alternative vote (AV) referendum, for example, they channelled funding to Labour-led groups that specialized in scurrilous and personal attacks on Nick Clegg – an episode that led to one of the few cases of real verbal fisticuffs in Cabinet. But as individuals they were invariably courteous and professional, and often likeable and considerate.

    This ability to operate on different levels is part of the modus operandi of all successful politicians and can be seen in the way the House of Commons constantly switches mood between elaborate good manners and boorishness, between real or synthetic anger and bonhomie. But the Tories appeared to have an exceptional ability to compartmentalize, to commit political murder with a charming smile. I worried that in its rapid ascent from the Championship to the Premier League my party hadn’t acquired this ruthlessness, and has paid the price.

    There was, however, in economic policy an underlying tension that was not simply between Lib Dems and Conservatives, or between George Osborne and myself. I believe that the structure of economic policy-making in government is badly flawed. I am far from being the first minister to lament the overarching power of the Treasury, full of highly intelligent and personable

    Enjoying the preview?
    Page 1 of 1