You are on page 1of 33

OECD PUBLIC MANAGEMENT REVIEWS: STRENGTHENING PUBLIC

ADMINISTRATION REFORM IN GREECE

WORKING PAPER V5

HEALTH CARE SYSTEM IN GREECE

Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:


Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

1
TABLE OF CONTENTS

 
Executive Summary.........................................................................................................................................3 
Foreword .........................................................................................................................................................5 
1. A Greek approach to health care..................................................................................................................6 
1.1.  A consensual diagnostic of the problem ...........................................................................................8 
1.1.1.  An unnecessarily complex system leads to greater inefficiency .................................................8 
1.1.2.  …and greater inequality ............................................................................................................10 
1.1.3.  A centralised system raises costs and decreases flexibility .......................................................11 
1.1.4.  Unmanaged conflicts of interest result in a corrupt system.......................................................12 
1.1.5.  Poor management results from a lack of evidence-based decision-making ..............................14 
1.1.6.  ….and a medically-dominated system.......................................................................................14 
1.2.  A consensual analysis of the results of reform................................................................................16 
1.2.1.  2000-2005: Stop and go reform efforts .....................................................................................16 
1.2.2.  Consequences of a failure to reform..........................................................................................17 
1.2.2.1.  Inequalities will, at best, remain unchanged and, most likely will increase..............................17 
1.2.2.2.  Inflation will continue to grow without obvious benefits..........................................................18 
1.2.2.3.  Health won’t improve without a public health policy ...............................................................19 
2. Some necessary elements to improve the management of the Greek health system .................................20 
2.1.  Build an information system on demand, consumption and costs ..................................................20 
2.1.1.  Detailed knowledge of morbidity and mortality........................................................................20 
2.1.2.  Measures of drug consumption..................................................................................................20 
2.1.3.  Measures of physician activity ..................................................................................................21 
2.1.4.  Measures of hospital activities ..................................................................................................22 
2.1.5.  Procedure and expertise to compute detailed tariffs for the above nomenclature .....................23 
2.1.6.  General, managerial and costs accounting systems for hospitals ..............................................23 
2.1.7.  Quality and cost control.............................................................................................................24 
2.2.  Plan and train the appropriate human resources..............................................................................24 
2.2.1.  Planning and controlling demography of the medical and paramedical professions.................25 
2.2.2.  Public health experts, hospital managers, medico-technical experts in biology, imaging,
informatics … ............................................................................................................................................26 
2.3.  Set the necessary conditions for allowing public hospitals to be managed.....................................27 
2.3.1.  Autonomy ..................................................................................................................................27 
2.3.2.  Stable resources .........................................................................................................................28 
2.4.  Informatics is not a panacea, but a help when the information system exists.................................28 
2.5.  The importance of primary care......................................................................................................29 
2.6.  Drug policy: favour generics and control prescription....................................................................31 
3. Conclusion .................................................................................................................................................32 

Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:


Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

2
Executive Summary

1. In spite of its still good performance in absolute terms, the relative position of the Greek health
care system deteriorates. Health indicators, such as life expectancy at birth, increase less rapidly than in
other OECD countries, when health expenditures rise at a fast path. Besides, the discontent within the
population is high and still growing.

2. The Greek system came from a superposition of reforms, rather than a progressive transformation
or a universal reform which would have given its logic. This unnecessarily complex system leads to greater
inefficiency: there are intricate organizations, financing mechanisms and responsibilities. The system is
both fragmented and centralized, which raises costs, decreases flexibility and increases inequalities.

3. Besides, if conflicts of interest are universal, there are poorly managed in Greece and, as result,
the importance of the underground economy is massive.

4. Given the intricacy of responsibilities, there are a poor management as well as a lack of evidence-
based decision making mechanisms. This, in turn, produces a lack of information and tools to analyse and
orient the system.

5. To this quite consensual diagnostic done by many reports and many reformers, whatever the
political orientation, Greece must invest time and money in order to built a manageable system, by that we
mean a system which can respond to local as well as national orientations. These are only necessary
conditions.

6. Greece should:

I. Collect information

• collect on a regular basis morbidity data in the population as well as in outpatient as well
inpatient medical facilities. It must as well control the quality of its mortality statistics,
• know precisely the drugs prescribed and consumed by categories of physicians and patients,
• develop appropriate nomenclatures to measure physicians activities in hospitals, primary care
centres, diagnostic facilities, laboratories, imaging and solo-practitioners,
• adapt a DRG system in order to measure hospital activities.

II. Build managerial tools

• generalize a double ledger and a cost accounting system in any health institution,
• create an accreditation procedure for public and private hospitals as well as an independent
institution in charge of implementing it,

III. Provide autonomy to its health care institutions and control them

• propose a by-law which will make hospitals independent enough to be managed, Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:
Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

3
• provide stability and clarity to hospital payment from public funds as well as social insurance
funds,
• control the efficiency and effectiveness of each hospital,
• control the prescription of drugs.

IV. Plan the provision of scarce resources according to medical and health needs

• plan human resources: doctors, nurses, public health experts, accountants, medical engineers,
software specialists,
• plan the adaptation of medical facilities according to both public health statistics and medical
technology.
7. A well coordinated effort could attain that goal in four years. The investment is low since Greece
could benefit from the experience of many other OECD countries. Besides, already, Greece spends money
in training a great number of medical doctors and part of the money could be reoriented.

This paper was prepared by Jean de Kervasdoué

Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:


Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

4
Foreword

8. The following report is not the first one to be written on the health care system in Greece. Other
national and international experts have analysed its qualities, as well as its major shortcomings. Greek
academics who have published articles and books and many actors, not only know it in detail, but have
ideas on what should be done in order to improve it. We do not pretend in a few months of intensive, but
limited, acquaintance to come with a magic solution. There are none, but there are several options,
including, of course, a continuation of the present state of affairs.

9. Only the Greek people will find their way to a more appropriate system and, as always in other
countries, it will happen step by step. Change never comes at once. It is important nonetheless to underline
some necessary conditions for such an improvement. Some are basic and seems simple, such as having an
accounting system in the public hospitals. Others are equally necessary, but are more political and certainly
less likely in the near future. One such is a global negotiation between the Government and the medical
profession on several issues such as: the number of physicians admitted in medical school, the level of
physician’ income in the public as well as the private sector, the relative role of specialists and general
practitioners.

10. As this is a working paper and not a formal review of the Greek health care system, we have
chosen to cover a wide set of issues in rather broad terms. Some judgements may seem abrupt to the
reader. Our intention is certainly not to offend any persons in charge, be it a politician, a civil servant or a
health professional. Nor are we seeking to embarrass any persons who so graciously agreed to meet with
the OECD team on its data collection missions to Athens. But the words we heard were not nuanced. The
situation is serious, both medically and financially. And, the saddest of all, it is likely to continue since we
did not trace internal political or social forces which could lead to a significant change. Why then try to
modestly contribute to change a system which seems to fit to the Greeks? Well, it does not. According to a
survey done by the OECD in 1999, only 18, 6% of the Greek population was satisfied with its health care
system. The relative percentage gave for the same survey a score of 83, 4% in Austria, 78, 2% in France,
55, 7% in the UK, 49, 9% in Germany.

11. The Greek population considers that health care is the 2nd most important issue after
unemployment. The increasing importance of private insurance is also an indicator of the lack of trust.
Since 1990, the number of privately insured Greek was 50 000, in 2008 there are around 1, 5 million.

12. It therefore seems to us that the Greek population is more fatalistic than satisfied. Indeed, how to
change a system which seems to fit to the political and medical elite? Major changes in social policy are
rare. Kingdon 1 argues that they must be at the confluence of three streams: the problem stream (a general
sense of urgency that a major problem requires action), the policies streams (the availability of acceptable
and feasible solutions) and the politics stream (fuelled by certain political events such as a change of
administration). There is a problem stream in Greece, but the policy and politics stream are, so far, weak.

Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:


Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
1
Kingdon, J.W. 1984. Agendas, alternatives, and public Policies”. Boston: Little, Brown and Company. Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

5
1. A Greek approach to health care

13. The Greek health care system is facing a crisis…

14. In order to have a global opinion of a health care system, three indicators are generally used. The
first has to do with health per se, it measures life expectancy at birth, a good synthetic indicator since it is
influenced by the cause of death at any age. In order to interpret it, as for any other indicators, one has to
look at its absolute value, as well as its rate of growth. The second is the global spending in “health” as a
percentage of GDP (Gross Domestic Product), it defines the global economical investment in medical care,
rather than health. The third is the percentage of medical expenditures financed by sate or social taxes, it
gives a fair idea of solidarity within a country.

82
Greece: Life expectancy at birth (Males & Females)
80 79,3
78,7 78,9 79,1
78,2 77,9 78,1 78 78,5
77,5 77,7 77,7 77,8
78 77,2 77,2
76,7 77 77,1
76 76,4 76,2
76
74,5
74
72
72
69,9
70

68

66

64
60

70

80

85

86

87

88

89

90

91

92

93

94

95

96

97

98

99

00

01

02

03

04

05
19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

20

20

20

20

20

20
Source OECD Health Data, 2007

15. Not all of the changes can be attributed to the medical system. Fifty years ago, Greece was
ranked second in the OECD in terms of life expectancy at birth, it is now in the fifteenth position. High
tobacco consumption, traffic accidents and obesity help explain that evolution. The average weight of the
population has dramatically increased with the change of food habits that are increasingly Americanised
and a low level of physical exercise. While the Greek population is relatively young when compared with
other OECD countries, it is rapidly aging which will also create new pressures for the health care system.

16. The global cost of the system, however, is escalating without obvious benefit. According to the
different official sources (OECD and WHO), the amount of health expenditures in Greece should be
around 10% of GDP in 2005, higher than OECD average (8,9%) for that year. But, given the importance of
“gray” economy in Greece, the real figure is certainly higher than 10%. The OECD was told that it
represents 29% of the total amount. If that is the case, Greece would spend 12,9% of GNP for its health
and would become the second country in the word for its level of health expenditures, after the USA and
before Switzerland.

17. Only considering the official figures, Greece had the highest increase in health expenditures since
1990 (almost 4% of GDP), while having the lowest growth in life expectancy at birth with the Netherlands
(2 years). Despite increases in health care expenditure, Greece has actually fallen in terms of global health Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:
Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
outcomes. Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

6
12
Greece : Health expenditure - % GDP
10 10,1
9,8 9,7 9,6
10 9,3

8 7,5 7,5 7,4 7,3 7,3 7,5


6,9
6,1
5,8 5,7 5,8 5,6
6 5,1 5,2
4,7

0
1970 1980 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005

Source OECD Health Data, 2007

Figure 2: Health expenditures and life expectancy growth

Life expectancy at birth and total health expenditure - % of GDP between 1990 and 2004
7,4
Korea
6,6

5,8
Life expectancy both sexes

5
(gain in years)

New Zealand
4,2
Finland Australia
Spain
3,4 France
Japan Germany
Sweden /
Italy United States
2,6 Canada United Kingdom
Greece
1,8 Netherlands

1
-1 0 1 2 3 4 5
Health expenditure (increase of % GDP)
Source : OECD Health data

18. In absolute term, the Greek situation demonstrates the low efficiency of the system, even, again,
when one takes only into consideration the official figures.

Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:


Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

7
Figure 3 Life expectancy at birth and share of health expenditures in GDP

Life expectancy at birth and total health expenditure - % of GDP in 2004

85 17

Health expenditure -% of GDP


Life expectancy both sexes (years)

15
83

13
81
11
79
9

77
7

75 5
d

om
d K den
da
a

ce

ea

d
y

s
ain
Ze s
ly

n
ec
an
ali

d
an

ate
an

pa
an

or
na

Ita

lan

gd
Sp
re
nl

al

we
st r

Ja

St
K
Fr
Ca

G
Fi

er

in
er
Au

d
eth
G

te
ew

ni
N

te
N

U
ni
Life expectancy Health expenditures U Source : OECD Health data

19. Since public funding of medical expenditures represents 50% of total expenditures, Greece has
the lowest level of solidarity within European countries (à verifier).

20. Despite these high levels of investment, public hospitals are bankrupt. In the last years, at least
10% of their budgets were not covered either by the State or by Social security funds. This explains why
suppliers are reluctant to sell to these institutions. At the end of 2008, the press even reported that some
firms withdrew their equipment because a lack of payment.

21. The health status of the Greek population, and the evidence of difficulty in the health financing
system, therefore require significant management improvements to the Greek health administration in
order to enhance its efficiency, effectiveness, probity, and financial sustainability.

1.1. A consensual diagnostic of the problem

1.1.1. An unnecessarily complex system leads to greater inefficiency

22. The following chart summarises the Greek medical care system, as seen from the patient point of
view. (Mossalyios, health economics, 2005 – Page S153).

Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:


Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

8
Figure 1: Organisation of the Greek health system: financing flows and delivery of health services

Private Doctors
(contracted by
NHS Health Insurance f-f-s
Funds) Direct payments
NHS Hospitals & Private or surcharges on
Semi-urban and f-f-s paid by
Hospital HIFs
Rural Primary IKA Services
Care Centres & * f-f-s
Primary
Capitations PMI
Rural Posts Care Per Diagnostic f-f-s
Centres diem
Centres

Per
diem f-f-s Contributions
IKA OGA OAEE Other Funds
Subsidies & for group
Staff Salaries contracts
Health Insurance Funds
Informal
Payments
Formal
Subsidies
Private
Payments
Taxes Contributions

Enterprises
(not for OAEE, OGA,
self-employed, or liberal
Population professions)

*OGA contracts private doctors for repeat prescription


Note: f-f-s refers to payment by fee-for-service

23. This intricacy reflects organizational complexity at the State level in a country where civil
servants are centrally managed. This is not only the case of the legal status of civil servants but, in Greece,
positions are allocated and filled centrally, staff is directly paid by the government, and local institutions,
such has hospitals, have no idea of the costs of personnel, that is at least half of their annual budget. This is
the main reason why cost accounting has such a difficulty to be used in Greek hospitals. The Ministry of
Health and Social Solidarity is not the only public body concerned with assuring the health of Greek
citizens. The Ministry of Employment and Social Protection is in charge of the major health insurance
funds, while the Ministry of Defence supervises the army health care services, the Ministry of Rural
Development and Food deals with the delivery of health care to the rural population, the Ministry of
Mercantile Marine covers the sailors and their families, and the Ministry of Economy and Finance
supervises the fund for civil servants (OPAD). The Ministry of Human Resources has responsibility for
civil servants With the Ministry of Finances. The Ministry of Finance allocates budget. The Ministry of
Development fixes prices for drugs and has the responsibility for public procurement. The Ministry of
Interior is in charge of administrative reforms. And “Digital convergence” progresses with the help of the
Ministry of Economics and the Ministry of Interior. Besides, one should understand that, contrary to most
western countries, these Ministries not only organise the system, prepare new laws and decrees, but also
manage day-to-day operations, not an easy task in a fragmented system which seems to greatly lack
interministerial co-ordination. (See Working Paper H1)

24. Some of the present characteristics of the Greek health care system go back to the nineteen-
thirties. The major Social Insurance Fund, IKA was established in 1934. The other major funds go back to
fifties (self employed) or the sixties (farmers). They still play a very significant role. Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:
Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

9
25. The National Health Service was created in 1983. It added new financing mechanisms to the pre-
existing one. In short, public hospitals became free to the population. Health centres were created in rural
areas, delivering primary health care. But, of course, this did not change the existing systems such as
IKA’s. Each additional set of services was layered on the top of existing one. Only public hospitals are
universally accessible, since health centres are not accessible in urban areas. In practice, there are several
systems in Greece, they vary according to the location, the profession and the level of income of the
potential patient.

26. After reading the literature on the state of the Greek health care system, one is struck by the high
degree of consensus between different authors regarding the results of this complex system.

27. Mossialos et al. (2005) 2 summarize it: “The current system is characterized by a high degree of
centralization, fragmentation of coverage, a regressive system of funding, inequitable coverage and access
to health services, distortions in the allocation of resources, perverse incentives for providers, escalating
costs and heavy reliance on relatively expensive inputs”.

28. The EURO HEALTH index 2007 computed by “Health Consumer Power House”, confirms it.
On its major index Greece is classified in 22nd position out of 29 countries. It only precedes Bulgaria,
Hungary, Lithuania, Poland and Romania, countries which spend between two to four times less than
Greece. And its rank would be the lowest if Greece did not have a good score on the dimension: “Patient
rights and information”.

1.1.2. …and greater inequality

29. Although seemingly offering complete health coverage for all Greeks, the chart in Figure 1 can
also be misleading. Greece has a mixed public and private financing system for health care with one of the
highest percentages of private financing in the OECD, after the United States. Public coverage for Greeks
is limited to NHS hospitals and primary care centres in semi-urban and rural areas. For care through
private hospitals and diagnostic centres, a person has to pay directly or subscribe to a private insurance
which then provides a reimbursement. Only IKA members have access to IKA primary care centres (which
cover roughly have of the Greek population and provides the most complete geographical coverage), and
care by private doctors is only partially reimbursed by health insurance funds.

30. The system is universal in principle, but not in reality since, even within NHS hospitals, money
makes a difference. In public hospitals, a patient still has to pay out of his/her pocket in order to get basic
services such as non-medical nursing care during off-hours, which are provided by private nurses at the
patient’s expense (or that of his/her family). In principle, a patient can access freely to an outpatient visit
with a specialist in a NHS hospital, but s/he will then have to wait several weeks or months before getting
his appointment. On the other hand, the same appointment, with the same doctor, in the same hospital can
be obtained almost immediately with a private payment.

31. Every health care system is inequitable. In any country, life expectancy varies according to sex,
social class, regions. There are also territorial differences for the supply of doctors, hospital beds, and
diagnostic equipments. The political question is then the degree of inequity. It exists in Greece but is quite
difficult to appraise due to the lack of good recent data.
Διαγράφηκε: ¶
Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:
Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
3
http://www.health-inequalities.eu/ Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

10
32. The number of doctors per thousand inhabitants varies between Central Greece (2,9) and Attica
(6,5) as well as the number of hospital beds: 2,8 in Central Greece and 5,6 in Attica. Mortality rates differs
also, but are not always linked with average income since it is high in East-Macedonia (7, 68 per thousand
inhabitants) and low in Epira (6, 2), two poor regions. The number of visits to doctors varies between
upper and lower social classes by 30%, but the rate of variation for certain tests is much higher: 100% for
the “PSA” test which contributes to the diagnosis of prostate cancer. Type II diabetes is present in 3% of
the members of the highest social class and 6,2% of the lowest.

33. These scattered data, mostly accessible through European sources 3 , demonstrates the low
prioritization in Greece of public health issues. One of the absolutely necessary conditions for an effective
public health policy would be detailed knowledge of the variation of health indicators, of health
determinants, as well as of medical supply through time and space.

1.1.3. A centralised system raises costs and decreases flexibility

34. Managing a hospital is, everywhere, a difficult endeavour. Caring for a patient requires the co-
ordinated advices of several medical specialists, as well as the attention of numerous other professions and
occupations. There are always several processes going on simultaneously, each with its own logic and
imperatives. Errors are frequent and can have severe consequences for the patient. According to the
international literature, 85% of medical errors are managerial errors. Organising a planning for nurses in a
ward, or an operating room, is always difficult. With the specialisation of medical care, not only does co-
ordination become more complex, but the type of equipment required becomes more and more specialised.
There exist at least 300 000 different references just for biomedical equipments and other medical goods,
to which 8 000 drugs could be added. Every day the patient load evolves, and the staff is then not always
adapted to the changing demand. Besides, employees have their own lives. Hospital managers, head
nurses, even doctors, must adapt. In such an environment, sociologists of organisations 4 have demonstrated
that, in order to perform, an organisation must be decentralised.

35. The necessity for decentralised and flexible healthcare management is therefore practically a
matter of international consensus. In Greece, however, another route has been chosen: not only are
organisations very centralised, but they are in the process of becoming even more centralised. The
recruitment process is done at the national level. For instance, once a nurse is appointed to a hospital, if
s/he wants to move, and is given permission, s/he starts to look for another institution. When s/he finds it,
s/he asks for a transfer and soon leaves. Then, it takes between eighteen months to three years for her first
hospital to get another nurse. When the procedure is decentralized, that delays varies with the available
supply of trained nurse, but when there is no shortage as in some parts of France, this procedure takes a
month; when there is a shortage the hospitals waits for the new graduation of nurse from school in June.

36. The consequences of this type of inertia are a reduced capacity to provide adequate health care
services. In a hospital in the Athens area, opened two years ago with 14 operating rooms, only 5 are in use
today due to the lack of personnel.

37. Procurement in Greek hospitals is already bureaucratic and quite centralised, but under the new
law (35-80, valid as of 18 June 2008), it is in principle, in the process of becoming completely centralised.
A State Committee for Public Procurement was created with the objective of reducing procurement costs,
improving payment time (currently over three years), making uniform medical requests, transferring
Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:
4
Lawrence, P., and Lorsch, J., "Differentiation and Integration in Complex Organizations" Administrative Science Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
Quarterly 12, (1967), 1- Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

11
redundant materials from one hospital to another, and improving management of expired products. In most
European countries there are two types of procurements: the first category has to do with usual products.
The markets are passed at regular period (from one to three years) and each hospital unit (ward,
department) orders within the market, they don’t have to wait but the time of delivery. For a more
exceptional market such as the construction of a new building, the procedure for the market varies from
three months to one year.

38. In practice, the new centralised procurement procedure will not speed things up. To the contrary,
it is a very slow process that begins with the lowest level of hospital management (a medical ward for
instance) to its hospital, then through the regional administrative units which will transmit the demands of
the different hospitals in its region to the State Committee. The Committee might then look for some
opportunities for standardisation and go back to each hospital and later organise a call for tender, wait for
the answers and choose the best offer. Only then will the products be delivered to the hospital. Since the
procedure has been legally defined, at each step, a company can go to court and if the State isat fault, the
procedure starts all over again. In addition, the law specifies that the State Committee not have more than
40 employees to manage this very complex system (as of early-January 2009, it had a staff of 25 persons).

39. In the meantime, hospitals have to treat patients. They need supplies and use the vendors which
were supplying their hospitals in 2002. We were told that currently (January 2009) “75% of the contracts
were illegal”.

40. This situation will not change any time soon. Under its current set of legal constraints, the system
cannot deliver the expected time and financial benefits, including the 500 million Euros of announced
potential savings. The assumption that one gets a better discount if one buys a greater amount can be
empirically demonstrated for an identical time schedule, but, de facto, the new procedure will take more
rather than less time. And potential savings can be substantial if, and only if, the buyer has the capacity to
negotiate. This is rarely the case, however, for public tenders. In comparison, even in France where the
procedure is more adaptable and completely decentralised at the hospital level, procurement in public
hospitals is more costly than similar transactions in private hospitals, even though they tend to be much
smaller than public hospitals (and therefore offer fewer opportunities for benefits of scale). Speed of
payment and the capacity to negotiate have made the difference. The OECD did not receive an official
answer to its request for information on the order of magnitude in the difference in cost between public and
private hospitals. It is clear, however, that the cost difference for procurement is important 5 . What counts
is not the quantity of the order, but rather the reputation of the client and how fast it can pay. Under the
new law, there is no direct negotiation between the user and the producer and, so far, no more money to
pay the suppliers on time. Centralisation is not an efficient way to protect against corruption, not only
because there are a great number of people involved at every stage of the procedure who can, at least,
retard it, but also because the potential conflict of interest remains intact. Private firms have demonstrated
that procurement must be decentralized at the appropriate level, that level depends on the type of product
and the nature of the supplier. In order to fight corruption, procedures are never sufficient, control with
potential sanctions is.

1.1.4. Unmanaged conflicts of interest result in a corrupt system

41. As indicated earlier, the “underground economy” in Greece is substantial, amounting to an


estimated 29% of total “official “expenditures”. A survey done among patients of public hospitals found
that 49% of them gave directly money their physician. Of this 49%, 39% of them reported that they did so
Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:
Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
5
Between 50% to 300% according to unofficial estimates. Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

12
willingly, 12% said: “I did what I was told” and 49% paid only after they were “pressed” to do so in order
to be treated. The OECD was also told of anecdotes in which “vignettes” (i.e. the proof of purchase) were
sold without the accompanying drug in order to allow illegal reimbursement claims. Unfortunately, the
OECD, however, was not able to substantiate these and many other similar stories with evidence.

42. What is the most striking is not the corruption itself but the lack of control in the situation where
there is a potential conflict between the patient and his physician. The basis of medical deontology, also of
Greek origin, assumes that a doctor always defends his patient’s interest. In many situations, everywhere,
there is a de facto potential conflict between the interest of the patient and the interest of his physician. As
Bernard Shaw once said, you should not trust a fee-for-service surgeon any more than a general sold to the
enemy, since the surgeon has a personal interest to cut your leg. So the problem is not the potential for
conflict of interest, which is universal, but the lack of control of any real, as opposed to potential, abuses.
For instance, in Greek public hospitals, doctors have a public practice in the morning and a private one in
the afternoon. In the first case, it takes several weeks -- even months -- to get an appointment; in the other,
less than a week. They also receive from the hospital 12% of the turnover induced by their patient.

43. Dichotomy is also a very frequent practice. A physician who refers a patient to a cardiac surgeon
gets 30% of the global “allowance” paid directly by the patient or by his/her private insurance company to
that surgeon (30% of 10 000 Euros). In the touristic part of the country, it has been reported that there is an
organised network between hotels, taxi, doctors and private hospitals. Doctors are paid 200 Euros for a
visit and hospitals up to 3 000 Euro per day for a “normal” disease.

44. Generic prescriptions in Greece represent only about 10% of the pharmaceutical market, as
compared to 60% in Germany. Old, but efficient drugs are also not prescribed. The Government has not
tried to explain that generics are as efficient as the original drug. They are authorised, but the interest
among doctors to prescribe them is limited, despite the huge potential for cost savings since their price
tends to be only 80% of the price of the original drug. Generics are constraints. Besides the false believe of
being a “cheap” version of the drug, they don’t have the same shape and the same colour, they change the
patient’s habits. , Finally, in Greece, new drugs which are substituted to ancient one, often as efficient, and
certainly much less expensive. Innovation is not always a systematic improvement.

45. This pattern of prescriptions is the clear result of the influence of the pharmaceutical industry
(which has argued that Greeks simply prefer branded drugs). In fifteen years, between 1990 and 2004,
pharmaceutical expenditures in Greece have multiplied by a factor of 7 (from 413 to 2 916 million Euro)!
The local production of pharmaceutical products represents 15% of the consumption and employed, in
2004, 4 951 employees, a relatively small number given the Greek population. Nevertheless, it has been
powerful enough to obtain the suppression of any positive reimbursement list (law 347, May 2006). All
prescription-only-medicines are reimbursed by social security, and drugs can be bought at a pharmacy
without any medical prescription. Indeed, as the pharmaceutical industry puts it: “the new reimbursement
system is expected to improve patient access to drugs and especially to new drugs” 6 .

46. So, in spite of a low price index (73 compared to EU average of 100), pharmaceutical
expenditures continue to grow by double digits (10%) in 2006. The turnover of the industry grew by 15,
8% in 2005 and the return on equity of the four leading company that year was 36, 2% which is a dream
for most companies.

Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:


6
Hellenic Association of pharmaceutical companies: “The Pharmaceutical market in Greece – Facts § Figures””, Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
Athens 2008, page 59. Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

13
47. For medical equipments, such as a pacemaker, a doctor will receive 15% of the total price of that
device. The conflicts of interest between the population, the health insurance funds and the State on one
side, and doctors and industry on the other is obvious, and unfortunately, to the advantage of the latter.

1.1.5. Poor management results from a lack of evidence-based decision-making

48. In order to improve the efficiency of service production and to reduce conflicts of interest, any
health system needs to be actively managed using information about the costs of production and the quality
and type of inputs. Yet in Greece, no one seems to know how much it costs to produce health goods.
Hospital administrators have no control over their budget and therefore no management tools or incentive
to control costs. The lack of information at the national, as well as the local, level is striking. Money is not
counted in public hospitals or in primary care centres. That implies, without playing on words, that it does
not count. The top health civil servants speak of a double-ledger accounting as an innovation 7 . Due to the
lack of appropriate information systems, the lack of nomenclatures, it is impossible to have an idea of what
is done in diagnosis centres and in hospitals. Of course, some physical indicators, such as the number of
admissions or the number of visits, are measured. However, nobody knows precisely what patients are
treated and at what cost.

49. This explains why, at the national level, there are no health accounts.

50. The OECD was told that a national survey on the health of the Greek population takes place
every five years, but it has been unable to get access to any results or to see if the data is sufficiently
precise to yield regional and social indicators. Such data is essential to elaborate any public health
programme and adapt it to local situations. In addition, due to the lack of nomenclatures, there is an
absolute lack of knowledge about the morbidity rates of inpatients and of outpatients. There are also no
detailed descriptions of the use of either imaging or biological tests.

51. “The Minister is the law”, we were told several times. That surprising sentence implies that each
Minister is free to conduct his/her policies and to hire whomever she chooses, including hospital managers
and regional directors. The recent past demonstrates that, in Greece, there is no real continuity, even when
the same political party is in power. Not only do policies change with each Minister, but the same Minister
can also go through different phases. On average, during the last 25 years, a Minister of health stayed 18
months in charge. To complicate things further, as demonstrated earlier, the Minister of Health is only one
actor among many, each with different incentives that put them at odds with finding a consensual approach
to reform.

1.1.6. ….and a medically-dominated system

52. Since the first publications of Eliot Freidson’ work on the medical profession at the end of the
nineteen-fifties and the development, by this important American sociologist, of the concept of
“dominance” by that specific profession, it is obvious that doctors are powerful everywhere. However, the
Greek case seems to be an ideal-type of that dominance.

53. More than in other countries, today in Greece, health equals medical care, in spite of the fact that,
2 500 years ago, the Greeks showed us the essential difference between these two concepts, with a separate
Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:
Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
7
It was invented six centuries ago, by the bankers at the end of the Middle Ages. Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

14
goddess for health, “Hygié”, and a god for medical care, “Esculape”. Today, “Hygié”, as represented by
public health, is well thought of in Greece as an academic discipline, but lacks support as a political
concern. At the national level, efforts to support public health reforms have been underfunded, an
indicator that it is not a priority. While a recent concern for limiting tobacco consumption does show a new
interest in public health issues, it has appeared one or two decades later than in most western countries.

54. Of course, the dominance of medical care on health goes with the false belief that there is always
a medical solution to a health problem, a possibility to cure and a way back to a previous healthy state. The
OECD was told that 100% of visits to doctors resulted in a prescription, compared with 40% in the
Netherlands.

55. The Greek medical care system has a very low percentage of general practitioners (GPs) (around
20% of the medical profession), compared to other developed countries. They are mostly in rural areas, and
have both a relatively low status and a low income. The number of nurses by physician is also much lower
than comparable countries: 0,8 rather than 2 in France and 4 in most Anglo-Saxon countries. But the
number of CT scanners is one of the highest in the world (16, 4 for one million inhabitant), even higher
than in the States (13, 2)! Since the partial failure of the reform of 1983, the supply of medical has become
distorted. The system favours hospitals and specialists rather than primary care and public health.

56. Over the course of its interviews, the OECD developed the impression that the overwhelming
level of respect in Greece for members of the medical profession can result in insufficient checks and
balances on medical authority in the interest of managing costs, controlling conflicts of interest, assuring
accountability and transparency, and assessing the legitimacy of medical decisions. Doctors get their way
throughout the Greek health system, and indeed it is built to their advantage. “It is the lack of confidence in
doctors which leads to centralisation”, said one hospital director.

57. In 1994, two committees (one Greek and one “international”) were established to investigate the
system. After their reports, further work by three subcommittees proposed:

• “the unification of sickness funds and the decentralization of the provision (Sissouras et al.,
1995) 8 ,

• the new organization and management of health manpower (Dervenis and Polyzos, 1995) 9 ,

• the primary and public health network, including a new GP system (Moraitis et al., 1995) 10 ” 11 .

8
Sissouras A., Karokis A., Polyzos N., Theodorou M., (1995), Unification of sickness funds and the decentralization
of the provision, Athens, Ministry of Health & Pharmetrica (in Greek).

9
Dervenis C., Polyzos N., (1995), Study and Proposal on the Organization and Management of the NHS and the
Development of Health Care Personnel, Athens, Ministry of Health & Pharmetrica (in Greek).

10
Moraitis E., Georgousi E., Zilides C., Theodorou M., Polyzos N., (1995), Study on the Organization and function of
a Primary health care system, Athens, Ministry of Health & Pharmetrica (in Greek).

11
Nicholas Polyzos, Charalampos Economou, Christos Zilidis; “NATIONAL HEALTH POLICY IN Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:
Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
GREECE: REGULATIONS OR REFORMS ? THE SISYPHUS MYTH” (published at European Research Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Studies in 2008) - Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

15
58. These law plans were first “postponed” and then abandoned. There still has been no real
unification of the social security funds. (See Working Paper V4) This has certainly contributed to the
growth of social security expenditures (6, 5% in 1980, 8, 5% in 2000), since without unity the power of
negotiation with physicians is limited, and the main issue are prices and volume control. . This was mainly
due to the opposition of the two main doctors’ bodies.

59. In 1997, a new law proposed:

• the creation of 13 regional public authorities,

• the recruitment of hospitals managers according to international standards,

• the implementation of “clinical” budgets (while keeping the existing accounting system).

60. If many reforms to the Greek health system have been voted, the ones that have been
implemented are those that are favourable to the medical profession. The State seems to have difficulties to
counterbalance the strength of the corporation which deeply penetrates the different political parties.

1.2. A consensual analysis of the results of reform

61. The history of health reform in Greece shows that while there have been clear improvements in
technology and the availability of human resources, efforts to increase equity, efficiency and the quality of
the system have been limited. There have been some positive developments: in 1992, for example,
legislation for patient’s rights was introduced. It became easier to create new private hospitals. A new per
diem tariff for hospital was created and some co-payment (drugs prescribed for outpatients, inpatient
admissions) was put in place. Private provisions and private insurance developed quickly during that
decade. As demonstrated in the last section, there has not been a lack of good ideas on how to reform the
system, but overall, the path of health reform in Greece is full of dead-ends, discontinuity, and failure to
undertake systemic reform.

1.2.1. 2000-2005: Stop and go reform efforts

62. In 2000, a new reform plan proposed “200 points of reform”. These points were not substantially
different from any of those made over the two previous decade (i.e. an agenda of regionalisation,
organisation of hospital management, unification of primary care, unification of the main social insurance
funds, evaluation of NHS doctors…) What was new was the emphasis on public health, in particular the
definition of public health targets and the reorganisation of public health services.

63. This time, the regionalisation was implemented. Hospital management changed with the
recruitment of professionals, the creation of new departments (personnel training, information technology
and quality insurance) as well as the definition of new financial procedures and methods of management.
The unification of primary health care service, however, failed, as well as the unification of financial
institutions.

Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:


Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

16
64. In 2003 a new bill on public health policy was introduced but quickly inactivated. Then in 2005,
professional hospital management was abolished and reverted back to “political administration”. In the
same line, the responsibility of regional authorities over hospitals was limited as well as the tool of
regional health policy development. “Both the Law on Public Health Services and the Law on the optional co-
operation among social insurance organisations in the field of primary health care services were inactivated. The
doctors´ evaluation process stopped. None of the drafts of law prepared during the 2000-3 period was introduced
to Parliament.12 ”

65. This brief summary demonstrates that Greece tries:

• to build a consistent public health policy,

• to decentralise,

• to professionalise hospital management,

• to control the quality of medical care,

• to reduce inequities,

• to promote a drug policy and favour generics.

66. But, what is done by one Government is undone by the next without continuity, even inside the
same political party.

1.2.2. Consequences of a failure to reform

67. The results of stop and go reform are persistent inequalities and high inflation. Many reports have
been published and many sensitive ideas have been proposed. Useful laws have been voted. But there are
rarely followed by reforms. Existing social forces have been strong enough to prevent change which would
modify their real or perceived interests. Failure to reform, however, will lead to a series of striking
consequences in Greece.

1.2.2.1. Inequalities will, at best, remain unchanged and, most likely will increase

68. The present system is inequitable in every dimension. Some of the issues that can be observed are
quite universal, while others are more specific to Greece.

69. Geographical inequity: primary health centres exist only in rural areas. The density of hospitals,
diagnostic centres and doctors varies tremendously between regions.

70. Institutional inequity: IKA primary care centres are only accessible to its members.

71. Financial inequity: due to the importance of private expenditure (48%), the consumption of, and
the access to, medical care varies with income.

Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:


Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
12
In Polyzos and al. Page 12. Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

17
72. Fiscal inequity: in order to get similar coverage, the financial contribution to an insurance fund
varies greatly (from one to three) from one fund to the next.

73. Medical inequities: medical practices vary from one hospital to the next. The patient has no way
to know if his/her physician follows the “good medical practices” recommended by learned societies.
Doctors are not controlled.

74. Health inequities: health indicators vary with sex, income, education and geography, as
everywhere in the world. It is likely that, in Greece, however, these inequities increase with the place of
residence, though the OECD has not yet been able to find any detailed data to document this intuition.

1.2.2.2. Inflation will continue to grow without obvious benefits

75. Figure 2 shows that, if life expectancy in Greece grew by 2 years between 1990 and 2004 (one of
the lowest rates of growth in the OECD), its health expenditures grew by 4% of the Greek GNP (the
highest of the OECD countries).

76. There is an empirical paradox concerning health expenditures. Contrary to what one would
expect, the higher the direct payment by patients, the higher the inflation! The experience of the USA,
Switzerland, and Greece all confirms this relationship. In these countries, the growth of health
expenditures, even when there are at a very high level (e.g. USA, Switzerland), continues without any
obvious beneficial impact on the health of the population (Figure 3). Kenneth Arrow 13 noticed the
particularities of markets where information and medical care is asymmetrical. The patient feels sick, but is
not sure of the fact. Even with access to the Internet, s/he has a limited idea of what could improve his/her
state. If s/he feels better, s/he does not know whether the disease has been effectively cured or if there has
been a natural, and positive, evolution of the disease. This phenomenon is at the root of regulation in the
field of medical care. Who can reduce that asymmetry? How can this be achieved?

77. This paradox has a complementary explanation. When a patient feels sick and decides to visit a
doctor or goes to a hospital, s/he does not buy a good or even a service, what s/he is looking for is
confidence: confidence to be well treated in every meaning of that qualifier. The patient expects to get the
latest up-to-date care -- care that is adapted to his/her state of health. Due to the asymmetry of information,
s/he is unable to judge the real quality of the doctor. Absent other indicators, s/he will therefore believe
that the “good” doctors are the expensive one. In other words, the more one pays, the better the treatment is
expected to be. The reasons for this belief are not important, but the consequences are. Since “informal”
payment is the rule across the Greek health care system, even in NHS hospitals, the tariffs of the health
insurance funds or the salaries in the NHS are never enough. The system produces a specific medical
inflation.

78. The upshot of this analysis is that public financing (through taxes and social security) is not only
more equitable, but is also more efficient since it is associated with price (tariff) control.

79. It is important to note that solidarity has nothing to do with wealth, and everything to do with
recognizing the ‘other’ as one of the group. When the Count Von Bismarck created social security in
Germany in 1883, when France (1945) or the United Kingdom (1948) organised a public financing
mechanism for health care, the wealth of these countries was much lower than the present wealth of
Greece. The question is not whether or not health expenditures occur -- they do -- but whether they are
equitable, efficient and fair.

13 Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:


Kenneth Arrow, « Uncertainty and the Welfare Economics of Medical Care », American Economic Review, 1963. Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

18
1.2.2.3. Health won’t improve without a public health policy

80. Once, not so long ago, Greece was reputed worldwide for its long life expectancy and its
excellent food habits. As demonstrated in the introduction, this is becoming less and less the case. Obesity,
lack of physical exercise, tobacco consumption, violent deaths (e.g. by car accidents), among other factors,
explain the slow Greek improvement of its life expectancy at birth, which is even slower that for
Americans.

81. In a health care system dominated by medical doctors, public health has difficulty to find its
appropriate place. It took France at least twenty years, and several scandals, in order to do so, for the same
reason. Furthermore, Greece lacks the statistical data to build such a policy. Regulations in that domain are
inspired by EU, rather than drawn from the specific problems of the Greek population.

Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:


Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

19
2. Some necessary elements to improve the management of the Greek health system

82. To manage any system -- a farm, a factory, a hospital, a health care system -- it is necessary to
collect information on what that institution produces and how it does it. Does the firm or institution reach
its goals? At what cost? Are the human and capital resources put in place well utilised? It happens that, for
health institutions and health systems, the answers to these questions are quite universal and can be easily
adapted from other countries’ experiences.

2.1. Build an information system on demand, consumption and costs

2.1.1. Detailed knowledge of morbidity and mortality

83. What is the medical demand (a better word than medical “need” 14 ) of a given population? This is
a central question when one wants to meet that demand, as every Government does. Measuring the
expressed demand for care is, in principle, easy. In order to do so, one has to collect the appropriate
information at the point of delivery. However, if one desires to measure the demand itself, and not only
how it is expressed, as will be demonstrated below, there is only one way: organise a detailed survey of a
representative sample of the population. This implies, of course, visiting their home, collecting
retrospective data on their medical history and their feelings about their health status.

84. Such surveys are long and expensive. In most western countries, there are done only every five to
ten years with a sample, at the national level, of roughly 5 000 inhabitants. The results, which take at least
one year to be published, cannot be used as managerial tools: they are used to understand how the health of
the population evolves, what are its relative trends, what is the potential demand, what are the social and
regional inequalities. As noted earlier, such surveys are conducted in Greece, but absent any information
on their results, the OECD cannot determine their quality of design, their rigour, or their impact on health
policy.

85. On an annual basis, mortality data are used in order to know the absolute and relative cause of
deaths and the evolution of life expectancy at different ages. This is a precise, easy to compute, indicator.

86. For medical care policy, rather than “health” per se, most of the time for day-to-day operations
what is measured is the “expressed” demand, i.e. the reasons why a person goes to a pharmacist, a
physician or a hospital and – of equal importance -- what that person buys and what treatment s/he
receives.

2.1.2. Measures of drug consumption

87. It is now quite easy to know what drugs are bought and by whom. While such information does
not reveal much about whether a drug has been used effectively, it is already important information.

88. In order to collect such information, the following components are required:

Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:


14
“Needs” are either sell defined or defined by the medical profession, arguments in a negotiation, there are Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
potentially infinite. Many workers would “need” a helicopter go back and forth to work. Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

20
• a national nomenclature for every drug, with its specific barcode;
• eventually another nomenclature for health insurance funds on the same vignette, with its own
barcode;
• Computers in each pharmacy;
• Information on the patient (e.g. age, sex, place of residence, type of health insurance fund at each
point of sale.

89. The OECD has understood that, in Greece, there is a barcode per drug, but that the identity of the
patient is not registered at the point of sale. Of course, a “smart card” provided by the insurance fund
would help to achieve that goal. IKA seems to be the first fund ready to implement such a project. A
universal system, however, is necessary to collect national data, regardless of insurance fund affiliation. To
achieve this, not only would smart card initiatives need to be generalised to other funds, but they would
need to share a common set of standards and data definitions in order to be able to pool and share data and
to permit interoperability with individual pharmacy systems and national databases.

2.1.3. Measures of physician activity

90. In the last fifty years, more and more precise measures of physicians’ activities have been
proposed. The first detailed, up-to-date and modifiable nomenclatures were invented for the most technical
areas of medicine: surgery, biology, imaging, radiotherapy and the like. They exist, to some extent,
everywhere, but are not always revised at the proper speed, the reason being that it has an impact on
physicians’ income. It is always easy to pay more for a given procedure or diagnosis, but more difficult to
advocate a productivity gain and a lowering of a given index or tariff. In addition, in order to give life to
such nomenclatures, a good team of technical, clinical and economic experts are required. This is the case
in the United States, Germany, and France, to name a few examples. When it is appropriate, in imaging for
instance, two separate nomenclatures should exist, one for measuring the clinical complexity and the other
its technical counterpart. In Greece, a working group for developing such a nomenclature for medical and
dental care was launched in 1996, under the responsibility of Doctor Phenikos. It worked for four years
with the Greek learned societies. His team was composed of medical doctors as well as certified
accountants. Starting from five foreign nomenclatures (British, French, German, Spanish and US) and
some field work, he proposed an original classification adapted to Greece and then asked the
representatives of each medical specialty to validate his classification as well as the relative ranking of
each procedure. His final report was given to the Minister in 2000. The Minister told the chairman how
highly he thought of him and of his contribution. A law was required, it never passed. As Doctor Phenikos
puts it to-day, it was a fascinating and “a life threatening experience”. When the classification was finished
he was threaten, his phone rang day and night; his colleagues wanted to demonstrate their discontent.
Biologists, pathologists, radiologists were afraid of the application of this new and logical endeavour. To-
day, every hospital has its own coding system. Social security funds also have theirs, with tariffs which
have not been revised for 18 years. However, in 2009, the Greek Ministry of health, asked a consulting
firm to propose a complete nomenclature. The first meeting took place in Athens in marc 2009.

91. The application of the methods to purely clinical expertise is less developed. Of course, every
system differentiates between a visit to a general practitioner, a specialist, a paediatrician or a psychiatrist
and, consequently, has a sort of nomenclature. However few systems measures on a day to-day basis, the-
reason-why-a-patient-goes-to-see-a-physician. That periphrasis is necessary since a visit is not always due
to a medical problem. For instance, in most western countries, when a child wants to practise a sport, s/he Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:
Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
has to visit a doctor who decides whether s/he is fit to engage in that type of physical activity. An Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

21
interesting experiment is going on in Creta, but has not yet been generalized. Such nomenclatures exist; for
example, one is Canadian, another is Austrian (Braun’s Kazugraphy).

2.1.4. Measures of hospital activities

92. Since the innovative work of Robert Fetter at Yale University in the nineteen seventies,
Diagnostic Related Groups (DRG), or DRG-like, nomenclatures have been used all over the world. That
unit measures a posteriori the reason why a patient stayed in a hospital. It is both a clinical and an
economical unit of measurement. Properly collected and controlled, it describes precisely the activities at
the hospital, ward and physician level. With limited geographical information on each patient, that system
also permits one to estimate local demand as well as the preferences of residents of a given geographical
area for one hospital over another. It is a prerequisite for applying marketing techniques to hospitals.

93. So far in Greece, there is no shared and universal database on equipment, personnel, visits, rate
of occupancy, medical expenditures and, most of all, activities measured by a standard universal unit of
measurement such as through a DRG. Greece has just decided to develop DRGs in 2009. It should choose
the best system from its point of view and for doing so, among the several DRG scales available; pay a
great attention to the frequency and the quality of the process of revision. It is a long and complex political
process, but one that several countries have gone through and Greece would do well to sign a partnership
with the country of its choice. Whatever the system for paying a hospital: price, tariff or global budgeting,
a unit for paying or computing a budget is always required. One needs to answer to the question: what is
paid for? Since the early 1980, most countries have abandoned the per diem system for paying hospitals.
To give more money when a patient is kept longer does not make sense when, for instance, he his
hospitalised for a lens extraction. He does not want to stay longer in a bed, he wants to see well. This
explains why DRG diffused all over the world. They compute the service provided to the patient. In order
to compute DRG, of course an algorithm is necessary, but there are several on the market and they are
quite easy to access. More importantly, at the end of a hospital stay, the physician in charge must
systematically fill a simple form. It basically asks to collect data on five variables: the main diagnosis
(reason why the patient was hospitalised, coded with ICD-10), the associated diagnosis (ICD-10), the
surgical procedure (if any); age and sex. DRG require a nomenclature for procedures. According to the
countries, the level of details varies from 700 to more than 2000. It must be a national classification,
compulsory for public and private hospitals. In must be done in each hospital under the responsibility of a
physician, appropriately trained. The first use of DRG is epidemiological. It allows describing precisely
what is done in each hospital and, with some simple information about the patient’s address, what person
goes where, for what type of disease. The second application is economical. A tariff for each DRG can be
computed with a sample of Greek hospital, starting with the present average or median cost. Greece can
also import the relative value of foreign DRG and price it when it has evaluated the potential consequences
of the new tariffs on the budget or the income of the hospital. With an appropriate team, a complete DRG
system, adapted to Greece can be conceived in 18 months. Another six months is then necessary to train
physicians. The reactions to that method are strong for two main reasons. The first one is that it makes the
production of every hospital and every doctor visible. They can no more pretend that their activity is
complex when it is not. The second is that not only it facilitates benchmarking between hospitals in Greece
and abroad, but it changes the income of most institutions. Some gain and remain silent, other loose and
protest. This is why most countries choose to take a reasonably long period (from 5 to 8 years) to deploy
the system. So, nomenclatures, cots accounting and DRG goes together. In France, he took three years to

Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:


16
Georges Bernard Shaw said, a long time ago, that « one should trust a fee-for-service surgeon as much as general Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
sold to the enemy. The former has a personal interest to cut your leg”. Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

22
build, test and diffuse the system: a new nomenclature, a DRG classification and a cost accounting system.
A year was necessary to recruit and train the physicians in charge of medical information. Hardware is not
a problem: for the largest hospital all the information can be store on a personal computer. But, after the
first enthusiasm, for political reasons, it took ten years to be partially in place, and almost twenty to be
fully deployed. To-day, if there are a sufficient numbers of hospitals to compute the cost of each DRG, cost
accounting methods are not yet used everywhere.

2.1.5. Procedure and expertise to compute detailed tariffs for the above nomenclature

94. Economists assume that health professionals are “rational” which consequently means that there
are sensitive to the way they are paid. Hence, setting medical tariffs is a very important part of health
policy since it is assumed that doctors, like other human beings, will react to economic incentives. It was
reported to the OECD that the tariffs of health insurance funds have not changed since 1992. This helps to
explain not only hospital deficits, but also the importance of out-of-pocket payments for patients, as well as
the fact that some medical activities are not paid at their appropriate level. Medical technology evolves,
productivity increases in many areas (e.g. biology, imaging, even surgery); tariffs should evolve
accordingly with that trend, as well as with the general cost of living and other considerations. If setting a
tariff is always a political decision, nomenclatures and relative scales can be imported. The Greek state
used that method for pricing drugs. Of course there will discrepancies between that index and present
tariffs, and of course the representative of the medical profession will advocate using the most favourable
interpretation and will try to avoid adjusting to the mean, but this is also the price for the future of
solidarity in Greece. Transparency of tariffs is a necessary condition to share a feeling of equity and accept
a new method.

2.1.6. General, managerial and costs accounting systems for hospitals

95. It is striking that the Greek health system does not allow for cost accounting at the point of
delivery. This fact marginalizes it from the systems of most other OECD countries and implies a limited
knowledge of the purpose of expenditures at the national level, most notably how much is spent for
manpower, drug, medical equipment, laundry, heating, etc. Again, when money is not counted, that means
that it does not count and, consequently, that the delivery system will – and does – experience both
rationing and waste.

96. There is an on-going project in Greece to impose a double-entry accounting. This is obviously a
priority and should be implemented at a much faster pace. So far, only 12 out of 26 hospitals in Athens
have implemented this reform. Successful implementation, however, will require appropriate training and
standard computerised accounting software that has been selected, documented and used as part of the
training. It would also be wise to simultaneously introduce both double-entry accounting and cost (or
analytical) accounting in hospitals and health care simultaneously. The OECD was told that 4 out of 26
hospitals already had analytical accounting. This could be the case, but then, at best, it would be partial
since personnel expenditures are not included.

97. In hospitals, three types of cost accounting are required in order to have proper managerial
information:
Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:
• cost accounting by unit of production (e.g. a meal, a kilo of laundry, an hour of operating room, a Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
day in intensive care); Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

23
• cost accounting by unit of management;
• cost accounting by DRG.

98. This should allow Greek hospitals and primary care centres to have a balance-sheet and an
income statement. Within public institutions, it is necessary to explain to the tax-payer what service has
been provided with their money, how and at what cost and income statements are essential to do so.
Besides any institution, even a small primary care centres, use space, buy computers, want to invest and
deploy new activities. Balance sheets measure years after years how its assets evolve and how they are
financed. It also gives an indication of depreciation and how an institution survives through time.

2.1.7. Quality and cost control

99. In the Greek health system, budgets are a priori approved and a posteriori controlled. The control
is always done by a public or private external body in less than six months after the end of the year. This
time constraint is essential to take decisions on the management and the managers. Controls must have
consequences. Although the bureaucratic mind believes that rules are the most efficient way to control an
organisation, this never really works. Rules are easy to get around and, currently they are so numerous, that
they have become contradictory and inapplicable (see also H3 paper on Improving Regulations). Of course
some rules must exist, but as argued in the first section of this paper, managers must also have autonomy.

100. Given the specificity of hospitals, 56 years ago a new procedure began to be generalised in the
United States; it is called hospital “accreditation”. This approach has been copied all over the world,
sometimes under the title of “certification”. It can be compulsory, as in the case of France, or voluntary, as
in the case of the UK. While, at its inception, accreditation tended to be process-oriented, it is becoming
increasingly geared towards outcomes. The idea is simple: every four or five years, each hospital accepts to
be controlled by a group of “visitors”, usually composed of a physician, a nurse and a manager. They
verify if the different procedures and measures of outcomes, nationally defined and presented in a manual,
are effectively applied in that hospital. They write a first report that the hospital comments on. Lines of
action are suggested and the final report is published.

101. Quality control is the last dimension. The literature on the quality of medical care is
exponentially increasing. “Quality” does not exist in the abstract. It is a relative, or an absolute, attribute of
a good, a service, an institution or a person. So, when one speaks of the “quality of medical care”, the
important word is … care. It is necessary to describe what type of care one is looking at, in order to
measure its quality or qualities. This is the reason why a policy designed to improve quality starts with the
appropriate tools. These are: units of measurement, medical records and a subset of information chosen for
their importance. They can be specific to a disease or not specific (nosocomial infections). The search for
perfection in that matter has been the excuse used by the medical profession not to be controlled. Rough
estimates are better than nothing and, when published, demonstrate that quality can be improved
everywhere when transparency and accountability measures are put in place.

2.2. Plan and train the appropriate human resources

102. No health care system, even the most liberal, leaves to the market the planning of health care
manpower resources. Training a doctor is costly and uses a lot of public resources, it is also long since it Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:
takes roughly a decade to train a medical doctor, there is then no easy adaptation of demand and supply. Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
Besides medical care evolves, medicine is becoming more and more specialized and a double division of Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

24
labour takes place. The first one is within the medical profession which has between 50 and 100 medical
specialties; the second is among the other professions and occupations working within the system. The
French administration counts 184 of these inside its public hospitals and it takes public planning to forecast
the nature and the approximate volume for the necessary skills which will be required to-morrow. In
consequence, the Ministry of health must plan with universities and other public as well as private training
institutions not only the absolute number of trainees per year but also the percentage of generalists and
specialists and, within each speciality the absolute number. Many projects have failed due to the lack of
appropriate human resources.

2.2.1. Planning and controlling demography of the medical and paramedical professions

103. Greece trains more medical doctors than most OECD countries. Since most of them want to
become specialists, they often wait several years after their basic training in order to be accepted in a
program. Hence they sometimes finish their medical school in their mid-thirties. Their professional life is
therefore shorter than that of their foreign counterparts, which contributes to their desire to achieve a high
annual income. This is exacerbated by the fact that general practitioners in Greece are not as highly valued
as specialists. Greece, like the United States, has an unbalanced medical profession. There are too many
specialists and not enough general practitioners. In addition, there are a relatively small number of nurses
by physician.

104. For many of the reasons already described, Greece, like France, has chosen the most expensive
way to produce care: through hospitals rather than outpatient care, through specialists rather general
practitioners, through doctors rather than nurses and through diagnostic expenditures rather than clinical
attention.

105. Demography is the most precise social science. Managing a demography means doing some
forecasts and, most of all, negotiating between the medical profession, the health funds and the
Government with one, and only one leader on the Government side. It is not enough to compute how many
GPs. Greece is going to train next year; one has also to think about the incentives of medical students and
their desire to work in remote areas. So far Greece obliges recent graduates from medical to work for over
a year in remote areas and distant islands but this does not seems to be enough. The problem of these areas
is not income but isolation. In principle, Greece would a perfect place to reduce that solitude by
telemedicine. Many projects were tested, but the necessary laws in order to have a routine use of
telemedicine were never passed. Another solution to prevent solitude is to allow medical doctors, nurses,
physiotherapists, dentists to create a common private centre, besides the existing public one, provided that
their access is open to social security patients and/or financed by public fund.

106. For ways to remedy the lack of GPs, Greece should look at Canada. By increasing substantially
the level and the mode of payment of primary care doctors, many specialists choose to go back to this
interesting mode of practice. Nothing needs to be imposed. Such a reform would probably be done at no
cost since international data demonstrate that a payment by capitation (and fee-for-services for night and
week-ends) decrease substantially the number of prescription by a far larger amount than the growth of
income. This is the reason why the pharmaceutical industry has everywhere opposed, overtly or not, such a
reform.

Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:


Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

25
2.2.2. Public health experts, hospital managers, medico-technical experts in biology, imaging,
informatics …

107. As has already been noted, the double-division of labour inside the system implies more and
more specialised training. New disciplines have emerged in the last half-century and they contribute to the
elaboration and to the deployment of health policy. This is not only true of the medical profession
(interventional cardiology, interventional neurology, neurocarcinology, rythmology …), but also for the
managerial as well as technical functions. Hospitals need specialized managers in marketing, in finances,
in human resources and cost-accounting. Hospital are the most technical building after nuclear power-
plant, these facilities require civil engineers, but also software specialists, bio-physicians and logistic
managers who can themselves be specialised for different types of products (drug, food, laundry) or
functions (lab tests, imaging).

108. Health per se, requires not only epidemiologists but also specialists of infectious diseases,
nutrition, toxicology, bio-informatics, mathematics, sociology, economics and political scientists. The
Government cannot always assume that this expertise exists outside and that it can contract it out when
needed. Furthermore, in order to pose the right questions to these experts and analyse their
recommendations, inside expertise is needed.

109. Specific training for hospital managers began sixty years ago in most western countries.
Progressively, courses in management were added to their basic legal curriculum. Hospitals are not only
heavily regulated institutions, but they are also complex ones. In order to promote this type of expertise,
appropriate training has to be offered, but this is just a necessary condition. Hospital managers must also
have the possibility of a career inside the civil service. Their promotion must be based on merit, expertise,
and skill. A system based on political appointments cannot motivate talented and dedicated individuals
since they know that, in the end, their talent will not be the principal dimension taken into consideration for
a promotion. So far, it seems that permanent training for hospital administrators is limited and that most
administrative “learn on the job”. Since 2005, the system has become based on clientalism rather that a real
public meritocracy.

110. Besides managers, hospitals need technical expertise. Bio-medical as well as civil engineers
should gain importance in the hierarchy, if the institution wants to be in a good position to negotiate with
private firms and contract with good internal expertise.

111. New types of jobs are also required. Hospitals need people with, not only a computer-science
background, but a nursing, a medical or a managerial training. Complex software on the managerial, as
well as the medical side, cannot be implemented without people able to adapt and translate the constraints
of the word of medicine, to the word of informatics, two separated words. Imaging with its “PACS” is also
computerised and the vendor should not be the only expert. In France, in the last two years, serious medical
problems were raised by the lack of expertise in radiotherapy, and some patients were over irradiated as a
consequence. At the local level, nobody was really mastering the software. They did not get, in due time,
the appropriate signals.

112. Diagnostics require a greater number of biological tests. Their importance is going to grow with
the importance already taken by bioinformatics. Of course, in order to perform these tests and interpret
them, the expertise will remain in the medical domain, but the process between clinical wards and
laboratories have to be managed. It is a problem of logistic which can have financial and medical
consequences.
Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:
Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

26
2.3. Set the necessary conditions for allowing public hospitals to be managed

2.3.1. Autonomy

113. Without making any judgments, in Greece political events have an impact not only -- as is the
case everywhere -- on policies, but also on managers of regional authorities as well as hospitals. In any
case, managers are currently limited to day-to-day issues that, while important, preclude the strategic
planning and management necessary to improve systemic performance. Most managerial decisions have
been replaced by administrative rules, interpreted outside the hospital by different bureaus, in different
ministries. Hospitals are, at best, administrated, not managed. Every appointment (almost) in a Greek
hospital must be signed by the Minister of Health.

114. Management is not a term reserved to private firms. There is such a thing as “public”
management with its training and reputed international journals. Hence, improving Greek health
administration management is not an issue of privatisation of NHS hospitals, but rather that unless public
management is improved, the present rules of Greek hospitals will continue to produce inequalities,
bureaucracy, costs, dissatisfaction of the public and a high political price.

115. Even if the personnel are regulated by public laws, and even if hospital employees are civil
servants, their management, i.e. recruitment, promotion etc., should be me made locally. One of the first
decisions of a manager is to arbitrate between different types of resources in order to improve the care
delivered to the patients. If personnel, the most important resource and source of expenditure, is
nominated, promoted and even assigned, by a bureaucrat outside the organisation, everybody knows that
not much can be done locally. Planning becomes de facto impossible and nobody tries to improve the day
to day organisation. In the case of a poorly organised system, the only way to give an acceptable service is
to increase the personnel. Inefficient systems are expensive and produce a high level of dissatisfaction.

116. Matters are aggravated when the Ministry lacks any basic precise data on its hospitals, in order to
allocate personnel and subsidies. In principle, the same accounting system, measure of output and quality
indicators etc., should apply to both public and private hospitals. It will then be possible to benchmark the
two types of hospitals and develop standards for public performance.

117. What should be done is consequently the reverse of what is presently taking place. Rather than
further centralization, Greek hospitals need to have a high level of autonomy on the managerial side and a
strict control on costs and outputs.

118. This implies, of course, that a universal cost-accounting system is first put in place under the
control of external accounting firms (or a public body) and a measure of production (DRG), with some
indicators of quality. Without such an accountability framework, guided by adequate and universal data,
then increasing autonomy can raise real concerns about the legitimacy of on-the-ground managerial
decisions.

119. As noted earlier, DRGs are on the agenda of the Ministry of Health, but the OECD has not yet
been able to get information on the precise timing for its implementation, on how it was going to be
managed, or on what DRG system was going to be chosen.

120. In order to pursue in that direction, Greece could look at the United Kingdom, Spain or Portugal.
In 1991, British hospitals became independent trusts -- private-non-profit entities -- owned by the NHS. Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:
Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
That reform gave them managerial autonomy. In Spain, since 2001, the system of concession authorizes a Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

27
private firm to manage a private hospital. In November 2002, Portuguese hospitals are autonomous. They
have the same by-laws that a private firm, but 100% of the shares are state-owned.

2.3.2. Stable resources

121. Today, public hospitals in Greece have three sources of income. Its employees are paid by the
State; health insurance funds pay a per diem for their members, and the State provides subsidies for
operating costs other than personnel. A fourth, and growing, source is deficit spending. Finally, hospital
employees, and perhaps hospitals themselves, also have a fifth source of payment: the “informal” one.

122. One cannot manage a system with a structural deficit. When efforts do not show and have no
consequences, why bother? The system seems to imply that large deficits are unavoidable, but they are not.
Health insurance tariffs are based on costs which go back to the early nineteen-nineties, they then don’t
cover costs and then if, in principle, the State pays only the salaries, it also ends-up by paying the deficit,
since social security does not contribute to its theoretical share.

123. The different solutions to this difficult political problem are well known. The quickest would be
that the State increases its global allowance, but it is outside of the scope of this report to choose what
would be not only the most appropriate, but also the most politically feasible level. Whatever change that
does take place, it can only be incremental. Whatever the solution, the amount of money used to pay
salaries should be transferred to each hospital. Hospital employees should be managed at the local level
even if some careers (e.g. doctors, hospital managers …) can be managed at the national level. As noted
above, these changes are predicated on information and accountability systems.

124. Budgets should be realistic and equitable, and the financing system should be based on a mix
between a case-mix payment (DRG or DRG-like), completed by subsidies for some public-service type
functions (e.g. emergency, training etc.). France, but also Germany, the Netherlands have such a system.
Although details vary, the idea is that there are services which can be paid case by case (DRG) such as
taking care of a patient who needs a hip replacement, but other functions are more global (training,
emergency) and need then a global financing mechanism.

125. The same principles could be applied to private hospitals. This does not mean that their tariffs
will be necessarily identical. There, also, the references are numerous, since most European countries
changed, at least once, the way they finance hospitals during the last thirty years: Germany, France, U.K.,
or the Netherlands. Most of them are partially or totally based on a case-based system.

2.3.3. Informatics is not a panacea, but a help when the information system exists

126. The use of information technology (IT) should neither be a priority, nor a limiting factor for the
evolution of the Greek health care system. Information is. Then, there are a lot of important informational
prerequisite in order to be limited by information technology. At the macro level Greece has not adopted
the OECD system of health accounts, because it does not have the information system capable of giving
detailed data such as: the break down between the different types of care (hospitals, outpatient facilities,
private practitioners …), or between public and private expenditures. We saw that there is no common
nomenclature between the State, social security funds, diagnostic centres and hospitals to measure medico- Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:
Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
technical activities. There is no double ledger accounting in the majority of Greek hospitals. Each Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
insurance has its own financial structure. So, even if each part is, of course, using computers for certain Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

28
functions, this will never form an information system. Of course, given the magnitude of the gap to be
filled Greece can simultaneously work on its information system and its informatics per se. International
technical standards, such as HL7, should be imposed on software manufacturers but, again, Greece has first
to invest in writing accounting instructions for both the producers and the financers of care. It has to define
nomenclatures not only for medical activities but categories of institutions, type of manpower and the rest.
Greece could use and, most of the time copy, what has been done in France by: La formation “Santé -
Protection sociale du Conseil National de l’Information Statistique” (CNIS) in France or by the National
Institute for Health and Clinical excellence in the United Kingdom.

127. E-health cards, e-claims, and e-payments are all on the health reform agenda, but their efficient
use implies some informational and procedural prerequisites. Where they are in place, computers will be of
great help. As mentioned earlier, health insurance funds could benefit from smart cards in order to limit
paper work and to improve information on costs. (See also V4 Working Paper on Social Security)

128. “Enterprise Resource Planning” (ERP) software could integrate the different financial and
medical data, where they exist, thereby improving individual efficiency and contributing to a better overall
picture of the management environment.

129. Computerised medical records will improve co-ordination and allow hospitals to control the
quality of care, but they imply important and stable resources (3 to 4% of the hospital budget), discipline,
motivation and training of, at least, 50% of hospitals employees. Such a system works is procedures exists,
and if everybody is involved. When all the national and local prerequisite are fulfilled, when
nomenclatures exist and procedures are defined to precisely know at anytime who is a patient of an
hospital, what are the doctors who can prescribe, what is the drug list, what are the protocols, what is the
bare-code system for drug, patients, equipment, when there is a hierarchy powerful enough to impose a
system to every physician, it takes at least four years to share through medical records relevant information
and four more years to benefit for integrating medical knowledge. The problem is that the prerequisites are
long and expensive before any benefit of that collective discipline become tangible. Let us lastly underline
that any investment in having good procedures and “paper” medical records will save a lot of money when
time comes to computerized them.…

130. Given its geography, Greece is one of the European countries which could benefit the most from
telemedicine. It requires a legal framework in order to follow the EU directive issued in January 2009. So
far, the experiments have not gotten past the testing stage, this is due to the lack of governmental support
and definition of an appropriated method of payment. There is an abundant literature on that technology. It
can help in specific situations. However, one should not expect any basic transformation of the delivery of
medical care. The Internet has already produced the fundamental shift. Not much more can be added at the
State level, besides securing medical files transfer and defining specific services for the most remote part
of the population.

2.4. The importance of primary care

131. Some health care systems in the world, and most notably the British, have been able to keep an
important role for their general practitioners. In England, GPs are well paid, rarely work in a solo-practice,
and can be accessed directly without any direct payment by the patient. Chosen by the patient, his/her GP
acts as a gateway to more specialised treatments and will limit access to hospitals and prescription of
drugs, tests and radiological exams to what is necessary. It is, in the United Kingdom, a prestigious
Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:
occupation. There are paid mostly (65%) through capitation. There are only three ways to pay physicians;
Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
two of them are used in Greece: Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

29
• salaries (which does not mean that the salary of every doctors should be identical across regions
and medical specialty);
• capitation (the rule in northern Europe for primary care doctors);
• fee for service.

132. The benefits and drawbacks of each method are well known. In order for the “fee-for-service”
method to be effective, the “service” needs to be precisely defined, on the one hand, and its tariffs need to
be computed by a well diffused and known method, on the other hand. Furthermore, in order to limit any
unjustified prescriptions or visits, under a fee for service system doctors should be controlled in order to
verify the absence of over prescription since the patient, by himself, is unable to do so. As noted earlier, the
information between a patient and its doctor is asymmetric. 16 This should be most notably the case in
diagnostic centres.

133. In Greece, doctors in primary care centres are paid with a salary and private practitioners are
reimbursed on a fee–for-service basis. This is also the case for hospital’s doctors in their private practice in
the afternoon.

134. From what the OECD has understood, primary care centres are found in rural and urban areas.
They belong to the closest public hospital which does not favour their expansion. They tend to be
understaffed and underfunded, and nobody knows what money they have spent since they do not have a
separate budget. One interviewee stated that prevention is a “black hole”. Doctors in such facilities simply
do not have the time to try to educate their patient 17 .

135. There are projects to increase the number of primary care centres in urban areas. It seems that
they care mostly for the poorest part of the population, whereas IKA centres treat the middle class.

136. 80% of the primary care sector is private. When money is not a problem, if the case is serious,
most Greeks take an appointment with a physician working in a hospital during his private practice. For
more banal diseases, they go to see a private practitioner 18 in town and do not seem to restrict themselves
from the use of diagnostic methods. Prices in private diagnostic centres or private hospitals are not
controlled and are much higher than in most European countries. As has been explained earlier in this
paper, this leads to a built-in inflation. In any country there is only one market for professional expertise, if
income is not controlled in one part of that market, this has inflationary effect on the other part. Doctors are
acting rationally according to the incentives of the system.

137. In addition to the necessary information on nomenclatures, tariffs and prices for every public and
private physician in order to appraise the situation, primary care centres should be managed independently.
Doctors working in these centres should receive an income comparable to their colleagues’ average. For
public health reasons, private diagnostic centres should be controlled in order to avoid dangerous over
prescription. For economic reasons, physicians’ fees should be capped when they work either for social
security or for public hospitals. Income can be high, but inflation must be controlled. This is the case in
Canada where doctors works on a fee for service basis but above a certain level, besides their taxes as a
Canadian citizen, their pay a progressive tax in order to limit their incitation to prescribe more.

17
50% of the Greek population does not exercise.
Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:
18
Social security will only reimburse a small part of the fees since the State price list has not been revised for 18 Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
years (1991). Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

30
2.5. Drug policy: favour generics and control prescription

138. There is much scope for reducing health expenditures through drug policy. Not so much through
the control of pharmaceutical prices, which is already the case (even if the system of reference price can be
manipulated by the manufacturers), but by influencing prescription behaviour and habits. Over the last
decade many major drugs became “public”, and this will continue in the coming years. Hence Greece
could favour, with more efficiency, the development of generics. There are many quite well-known
methods to do so: quasi-automatic substitution by pharmacists from branded drugs to generics and, most of
all, tariffs. The present regulation sets the price of generics at a 20% discount of patent-protected product,
there is no reason why this should be so limited. Lastly, the Greek population could be informed that
generics are not discount products and that in many domains, such as antibiotics, more is not better but
worse.

139. Greece, for instance, could organise every three years an international bid (on price and quantity)
among the makers of generics and choose not necessarily the lowest (there are arguments for more
complex choice), but rather a limited number of producers, without limiting itself to a price rebate of 20%.

140. When there are efficient, and most of them are indeed, drugs are dangerous if used too frequently
or in a non-appropriate manner. Hence, for public health reason, they should not be sold without
prescription. Prescriptions themselves should be limited and controlled by the health insurance companies.

141. Besides, Greece should come back to a positive list of drugs and define what is reimbursed, at
what rate, under what financial and clinical conditions. These definitions should be permanently revised.

142. Because of the limited economic importance of the Greek pharmaceutical industry, a drug policy
should be relatively simple to elaborate. Greece should not have to balance between favouring its national
industry and trying to limit its health expenditures. As everywhere, the pharmaceutical industry tries to
influence doctor’s behaviour. Investing in marketing pays. This can be controlled by regulations such as
taxes on any advertising to doctors. Besides in many countries a doctor cannot accept any gift, trip or
payment from the pharmaceutical industry unless it is strictly linked with medical information. Although it
is very important that doctors keep at a given point in time the freedom to prescribe, the scope of that
prescription can be limited for a specialty and, most of all, these prescriptions can be controlled a
posteriori.

Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:


Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

31
3. Conclusion

143. The sequencing of the required reforms is clear. Some are already launched, sometimes for the
second or third time, but they will succeed this time, if everybody feels that this a stone to a house which
has its design, its budget and its construction schedule. In many areas Greece does not have to start from
scratch, but uses what has been done in several other European countries. It could then benefit, with the
OECD expertise, of the practical knowledge of a limited number of foreign experts, teamed with their
Greek counterpart. They could produce a public report every six months.

144. In three years, Greece could have its own nomenclatures including DRG, information systems for
health insurance funds, hospitals as well as its own body of health statistics and health accounts. 2012
could be a target.

145. Simultaneously Greece should launch a planning for its health care resources. This is of course
concerns the medical and paramedical professions but also the specialized jobs in hospitals management,
health care technology and medical informatics.

146. Then Greece has to search for a way of increasing the autonomy of its medical institutions. With
a team working on a by-law of the future “autonomous” (the degree of autonomy can vary) hospitals,
another team could define its managerial tools on the financial as well as the medical side. There, also, is a
very abundant literature and a lot of applied expertise in North America and western European countries.
Again a hospital is a complex institution. No rules can replace day-to-day decisions of tenth of managers,
nurses and physician. Administrate, define abstract universal rules in these conditions leads to costs and
frustrations. Of course, autonomy can only be conceived if there are strong mechanism of evaluation and
control, including quality control through accreditation and certification procedures.

147. Improving the supply of medical care needs to be tied with the overall objectives of the health
system. This implies that Greece develop a strong public health expertise at the regional level in order to
better answer to the specific needs of each region.

148. Of course, here and there ICT will contribute to this construction, but that technology is not a
magic stick and it cannot create an information system, so far there it has been a solution in search of
answers. Some expensive experiments were launched but went nowhere. Greece needs to orient, step by
step, its system toward performance and accountability, and for that go through austere, but necessary
reforms.

Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:


Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

32
Greece : GDP - /capita, US $ PPP
32000

28000

24000

20000

16000

12000

8000

4000

0
60

70

80

81

82

83

84

85

86
87

88

89
90

91

92

93
94

95

96
97

98

99
00

01

02
03

04

05
19

19

19

19
19

19

19
19

19

19

19
19

19

19
19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

20

20

20
20

20

20
Source OECD Health Data, 2007

Greece : GDP - /capita, US $ PPP


32000

28000

24000

20000

16000

12000

8000

4000

0
92

93
60

70

80

81

82

83

84

85

86
87

88

89
90

91

94

95

96
97

98

99
00

01

02
03

04

05
19

19

19

19
19

19

19
19

19

19

19

19
19

19

19
19

19

19

19

19

19

19

20

20

20
20

20

20

Source OECD Health Data, 2007

Μορφοποιήθηκε: Θέση: Οριζόντια:


Στο κέντρο, Σε σχέση με: Περιθώριο,
Κατακόρυφα: 0 στ., Σε σχέση με:
Παράγραφος, Αναδίπλωση γύρω από

33

You might also like