You are on page 1of 5

ARTICLE IN PRESS

Marine Policy 31 (2007) 535–539


www.elsevier.com/locate/marpol

Work sharing in Kerala’s fisheries


Marrit van den Berga,b,, Bart Jan Lensinga
a
Development Research Institute, Tilburg University, the Netherlands
b
Development Economics Group, Wageningen University, P.O. Box 8130, 6700 EW Wageningen, the Netherlands
Received 28 October 2006; accepted 9 December 2006

Abstract

Earlier studies suggest that once population growth and market integration reach a certain critical level, traditional practices of work
sharing tend to degenerate or disappear altogether. Work sharing has, however, survived to date in small-scale fisheries in Kerala, India.
Artisanal fishermen strongly favor the system, for ethical reasons as well as for their personal benefit. Besides, boat owners appear not to
be hindered by the system. Contrary to observations in crop production, work sharing has not inhibited the introduction of modern
technologies like motorization.
r 2007 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Artisanal fisheries; India; Work sharing; Informal insurance

1. Introduction and the hunusan system in the Philippines, all members


belonging to a given village community have a right to join
The artisanal fishery sector in Kerala harbors an in rice-harvesting operations and receive a share of the
informal insurance system against unemployment that output [2]. These systems started to decline after the 1960s
has since long disappeared from most other parts of the and have now largely been replaced by systems involving a
world. In traditional village societies, employment is limited number of laborers [3].
often shared among more laborers than necessary. This WS has, however, survived to date in small-scale fisheries
way income spreads over a relatively large part of the in Kerala, India. Along most of Kerala’s coast, a labor-
population: the laborers consciously agree to forsake part rotation system is operational. The key to this system is
of their current income such that additional people could open access to employment: every fisherman from a village
have access to work and income and thereby ensure their can join a fishing unit, even when no extra crew is needed.
livelihood. As a result, work is shared equally among the community
Earlier studies suggest that once population growth and workforce and involuntary unemployment does not exist.
market integration reach a certain critical level, traditional Because of this system of WS, every healthy fisherman gets
practices of work sharing (WS) tend to degenerate or a chance to earn a living and the excess labor is absorbed.
disappear altogether [1]. The open access system in the Despite the observation of Kurien and Vijayan [4] that
shore-seine1 fishery in Sri Lanka, for example, collapsed in system is under great strain, we find that it is very much
the 1950s [1]. A similar development can be observed in rice alive.
cultivation in South-East Asia. In the bawon system of Java The persistence of the sharing system seems a surprising
but favorable development. No fisherman is unemployed
Corresponding author. Development Economics Group, Wageningen and without income. Yet, there may be an unfavorable side
University, P.O. Box 8130, 6700 EW Wageningen, the Netherlands. Tel.: to the system. WS lowers the incentives to increase labor
+31 317 482548; fax: +31 317 484037. productivity and may thus limit economic development.
E-mail address: Marrit.vandenBerg@wur.nl (M. van den Berg).
1
Shore-seining is a type of fishing where a large net, which is attached to
Hence, the sharing of income through work spreading may
a rope on the shore, is set out close to the shore by a boat, where after it is result in the mere sharing of poverty [5]. The current paper,
pulled in from the shore by a group of men. therefore, covers two questions: (1) why has WS survived in

0308-597X/$ - see front matter r 2007 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.marpol.2006.12.002
ARTICLE IN PRESS
536 M. van den Berg, B.J. Lensing / Marine Policy 31 (2007) 535–539

Kerala’s fisheries, while it has disappeared in so many systems from breaking down. As shown above, however,
other situations, and (2) does the system constrain equality and poverty may be two sides of the same coin: the
economic development of the fishery sector? artificial preservation of WS may inhibit development and
The structure of the paper is as follows. Section 2 covers the increase of average income.
the relation between WS and development as illustrated by
the seminal book of Geertz [5]. Section 3 elaborates on the 3. WS among Kerala’s fishermen
workings of the system of WS practiced by fishermen in
Kerala. Section 4 discusses the sustainable of the system Kerala, situated in the southwestern corner of India, is
and its effect on development. Finally, the future of one of the foremost maritime states in India. The state is
Kerala’s artisanal fishery sector and its WS system is responsible for a quarter of total Indian fish catches and
discussed in Section 5. for 40% of Indian seafood exports [4]. Kerala is the home
of 182,000 active fishermen, and it has a total fisherfolk
2. WS and development population of 844,000 [6]. This group belongs to the poorer
sections of the population and has very limited access to
Perhaps the best-known example of WS is the Javan formal social security. The fisherfolk live in 223 fishing
system described by Geertz [5]. Geertz, however, did not villages situated along Kerala’s coastline. They are
use the words WS. His terminology reveals a rather predominantly Hindu and Muslim in the northern and
negative outlook on the practice concerned. Geertz central coastal villages and mainly Roman Catholic in the
analyzed the state of affairs on the South-East Asian southern coastal districts [7].
island of Java during the first half of the 20th century. Due
to increased health care provided by the Dutch colonial 3.1. Field research
regime, the population density increased sharply from an
already high level. There was no modern sector to absorb We chose to focus our research on the most prominent
the rising population, and virtually all Javanese found type of marine fishing in Kerala: ring-seine fishing. Ring-
employment in traditional agriculture. Work was shared seine fishing employs large outboard-motorized canoes,
between all laborers of a village. At harvesting, e.g., one- so-called thanguvalloms. Usually, the length of these
sixth of the produce was allocated to labor and all village boats varies from 15 to 20 m, and they carry 25–50
laborers were allowed to participate in the activity even if fishermen. Also the smaller discovalloms are used. Their
their marginal productivity was negligible [3]. As a result of length varies from 12 to 15 m, and they carry a crew of
the abundance of labor, there were no incentives to 12–25 men. Both types of boats use a long net with which
modernize production and per capita income remained they encircle a shoal of fish. When the circle is closed, the
low. Hence, Geertz spoke of ‘involution’ and ‘shared bottom of the net is tightened by a rope so that the fish
poverty’. cannot escape. Prior to the motorization of the 1980s, the
After the 1960s, Java’s traditional system of WS—or in ring-seine was only used in the districts of Ernaculam and
the terminology of Geertz: poverty sharing—broke down Alleppy. However, the system of fishing was so successful
[3]. Markets and new technologies penetrated the agricul- that it is now the dominant technique in nearly the whole
tural sector and landowners shifted from hiring laborers on of Kerala. In 1998, there were 2300 units in Kerala,
a share basis to wage labor. As a result of these providing work for more than half of Kerala’s active
developments, labor productivity increased and part of fishermen [8,9].
labor was driven away from agriculture. This labor sought The field study was conducted from June 3 to October
employment in non-agricultural activities. Hence, the 20, 2001. Based on the Census Report on the Artisanal
abolition of WS corresponded to a spurt in economic Fishing Fleet of Kerala [8], three villages were chosen with
development. a relatively large number of thanguvalloms and discoval-
The above indicates that WS is more than the sharing of loms. The villages were situated in the so-called chakara (or
employment and income between all people belonging to a mud bank) regions; the only areas where fishing is possible
certain group. WS affects incentives to modernize produc- during the monsoon season (June to September) when the
tion. When labor is abundantly available and employment sea is rough. The villages were selected such that they
is shared, there are no incentives to invest in new represent a large geographical and religious diversity. In
laborsaving production techniques. Put differently, WS is particular, sites were picked that could be expected to have
not only a system of mutual insurance and solidarity. It can different magnitudes of WS.
also be a barrier to development. The research started in Arthunkal, a village with about
In many regions, the development of a modern sector 6000 inhabitants and 1500 active fishermen in the southern
alongside the traditional sector has lead to the breakdown district of Alleppey [7]. Most of the population is Catholic.
of WS and the increase in average labor productivity in the Arthunkal is the berth of largest number of thanguvalloms
traditional sector. This has resulted in a rise in both in Kerala. It is regarded as the place of origin of ring-seine
average income and income inequality. The latter is the fishing and the central region of the WS system. According
reason that some parties try to prevent traditional WS to local scientists, government officials and fishermen from
ARTICLE IN PRESS
M. van den Berg, B.J. Lensing / Marine Policy 31 (2007) 535–539 537

Arthunkal, the WS system was either severely restricted or uprising of the 1940s, which resulted in the abolition of
even non-existent north of Alleppey. bonded labor in fisheries [4]. Karanila means ‘shore status’
The next research site was up north at Forth Cochin in and is used to refer to those crewmembers who stay on the
the Ernamulum district in central Kerala. Fort Cochin is a shore. The karanilas share in the catch of a particular day,
small village with about 2500 inhabitants and 500 active even though they have not contributed to this catch.
fishermen [10]. Most fishermen are Catholic or Muslim. Usually they receive 75% of a full workers share. This
Due to its location near the main fishing harbor of Kerala, share is called karapank, or ‘shore share’. It has a dual
the village attracts many fishing units from other villages. purpose: (1) to smooth intertemporarily the income for any
The presence of a harbor allows the use of inboard motors, particular fisherman, and (2) to stimulate the willingness
a technology that is increasingly used to power the large for crewmembers to stay on the shore to give others a
thanguvalloms. chance to go fishing in the boat.
The final site was even further north at the village of Two types of karanila system prevail in Kerala. Under
Chavacaud in the Trissur district. Chavancaud has about the first type, the ‘liberal version’, the fishermen who stay
5200 inhabitants, including 700 active fishermen [10], which on the shore must meet two conditions to receive karapank:
are mostly Muslim or Hindu. Originally Trissur did not
have a strong WS system. However, when fishermen (1) They should be regular crewmembers.4
from Aleppey went to Trissur to teach the local fishermen (2) They should be present to help with the departure of
how to use the ring-seine technique, they also spread the the boat in the morning, and in some regions also when
idea of WS. the craft lands on the shore.
The core of the study is a small survey about how, how In the second version of karanila, the ‘restrictive
much, and why the fishermen share their work, about version’ an additional condition is added:
social values, and about changes in the sharing system. (3) The other members of the unit should consider the
Fifty-five interviews were completed. The respondents reason that you want to stay on the shore as legitimate
were recruited randomly on the beach, after all boats were (illness, funeral, marriage, etc.).
back from fishing. All respondents belonged to different
fishing units.
Under this restrictive system, the excess men who stay on
The survey is complemented by information from
the shore consist of a group of men who receive karapank
discussion sessions with many experts and insiders, like
(because they comply with rule 3) and a group of men who
local academics, trade union leaders, governmental offi-
do not. Under this second type of karapank system, there
cials, middlemen and leaders of cooperatives. Besides,
usually is a fixed set rules that stipulates the number of
valuable background information was obtained from
karanila-days granted under specific circumstances.
personal observations that one of the authors made by
There are differences in the extent to which WS takes
going fishing, by monitoring the fish markets and crews on
place between various fishing units and regions in Kerala.
the beach, and by residing in the houses of local fishermen.
The 55 respondents were asked how many workers their
unit covered. Next, they were asked how many crewmem-
3.2. The WS system
bers were necessary to operate smoothly. On the basis of
these numbers, the percentage of workers that are super-
The WS system in Kerala is a system where income
fluous—the WS percentage can be calculated:
is shared between fishermen working on a single boat.
Every fisherman in a village (not only relatives and close WS  percentage
friends) can join a fishing unit, whether this unit needs actual number of workers  necessary number of workers
¼  100%.
additional labor or not. Part of the superfluous workers actual number of workers
goes along on the boat (simultaneous WS). The remainder
This percentage equals the share of their income that
stays ashore and comes along on other shifts (sequential
the fishermen sacrifice to continue the system of WS—the
WS).2 This way, work is shared equally among the (male)
WS-premium.
community workforce. The costs of this WS are borne by
On average, the fishermen sacrifice 26% of their income
the crew alone: the owners of the boat, net and engine
for WS, with a range of 2–57% (Table 1). As the fishermen
receive a fixed percentage of the catch as a return on
state that all community members are welcome to join their
capital.3
crew, differences between villages reflect differences in
The lubricant of sequential WS is the so-called karanila
labor surplus. Hence, the labor surplus appears to be
system. The system came into practice after the peasant
highest in Arthunkal. Since the fishermen are free to choose
2
There are no strict rules to determine when one should work and when the boat on which they work, differences in WS of boats
one is allowed to stay ashore. Some men jump into the boat within a village are likely to represent differences in
spontaneously. Everybody knows he should volunteer to work regularly,
4
and everybody keeps an eye on each other not to shirk, and to work no There is no strict criterion for being a ‘regular crew member’ but in
less than others. most units you are regarded as a regular member if you have worked in
3
In most cases 40%. In some cases 45% or 50% that unit for several weeks or more.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
538 M. van den Berg, B.J. Lensing / Marine Policy 31 (2007) 535–539

Table 1 Table 3
Average WS-premiums in the three villages The importance of karapank

N Average Minimum Maximum N % not willing to accept


(%) (%) (%) newcomers after the
abolishment of karapank
Arthunkal 22 28 7 38
Fort Cochin 9 46 30 57 Arthunkal 22 90
thanguvalloms Fort Cochin thanguvalloms 9 78
Discovalloms 8 22 11 34 Discovalloms 8 75
Chavacaud 16 14 2 25 Chavacaud 16 84

Total 55 26 2 57 Total 55 84

Source: Own fieldwork. Source: Own fieldwork.

Table 2 careful not to overvalue the importance of karapank, as


Distribution of liberal and restrictive versions of karanila system on most boats only part of all members staying ashore
N Liberal (%) Restrictive (%)
receives karapank.
In any case, the karanila system of work rotation cannot
Arthunkal 22 29 71 explain the survival of the WS system in Kerala. Problems
Fort Cochin thanguvalloms 9 100 0 with work rotation were not the cause of the breaking
Discovalloms 8 12 88
down of the Java system of harvesting rice. The system
Chavacaud 16 5 95
involved only simultaneous WS and hence did not require
Total 55 31 69 rotation. Hence, there must be other reasons why WS
Source: Own fieldwork. survived in Kerala’s fisheries and not in for instance Java’s
rice production.
Javan WS disappeared when rice production was
productivity. The largest WS percentages are found for integrated into the market economy. The landowners
thanguvalloms in Fort Cochin: 30–57%. Many of these started to remunerate their laborers on a wage instead
boats have inboard motors and are more seaworthy than of a share basis. This shift removed one of the foundations
the standard thanguvalloms. of the WS system: the remuneration of labor as a group.
All units in the three research villages practised one of The laborers were now rewarded individually and the
the two types of karanila system. On most boats, the employer decided on the amount of labor to be used. The
restrictive system is used and fishermen need a valid reason same was observed in other traditional WS systems in
the stay ashore (Table 2). The liberal system is only agriculture.
dominant for thanguvalloms in Fort Cochin, the most Yet market integration has not lead to the abolition of
modern boats in the sample. the share system of labor remuneration in Kerala’s
fisheries, as it did not in the fisheries sector in many other
4. Sustainability and economic development parts of the world. In fisheries, share contracts, where boat
owner and laborers share the returns, dominate wage and
Contrary to many traditional WS systems in other fixed rent contracts to this very day. There are powerful
regions of the world, WS in Kerala’s fisheries is very much reasons—in terms of both risk and transaction costs—for
alive. As shown above, we did not find ring-seine units that believing that the basis for these share contracts is very
did not practice WS. Besides, the fishermen are very strong and that the share system is entirely capable of
optimistic about the continuation of the current WS dynamically adjusting to changing circumstances [11].
practices. Forty-six out of 55 respondents confirmed the Hence, the share system of labor remuneration as a
statement that ‘‘the WS system will not disappear in the fundamental of the WS system in Kerala is not under
future’’. The other 9 answered that ‘‘only God can look threat.
into the future’’, or something of that kind. None of the 55 While the sustainability of sharing labor remuneration
respondents predicted that WS would disappear. is a necessary condition for the persistence of WS, it is
The fishermen regarded karapank as an essential part not sufficient. Sharing labor remuneration does not
of the WS system: most fishermen stated that they would necessarily involve sharing work. WS involves sharing
not be willing to accept newcomers to their unit if there the remuneration of labor between more than the required
would be no karanila arrangement (Table 3). As there are number of workers. Hence, the share system of labor
no strict rules about work rotation, there must be a remuneration gives laborers the opportunity but not
voluntary system of rotation. With the payment of the obligation to share work. In European fisheries, for
karapank, crewmembers have no problem staying back example, remuneration is often shared, but not work.
on the beach every now and then. One should, however, be Therefore, the question remains why WS persists in
ARTICLE IN PRESS
M. van den Berg, B.J. Lensing / Marine Policy 31 (2007) 535–539 539

Kerala, even among people that are not relatives or casting nets from the shore, and its labor-absorbing
close friends.5 capacity is low relative to ring-seine fisheries in Kerala.
At least part of the answer lays the absence of threats Fortunately, Kerala is renowned for its relatively slow
to the system within artisanal fisheries. Given shared population growth, and the number of active fishermen
labor remuneration, the WS system practiced in Kerala even decreased between 1998 and 2005 [6,10].
does not present costs to the owners of capital: the A more pressing threat to the WS system may be the
share of returns allocated to the boat owner is independent demise of the sector as a whole. Rapid modernization of
of the number of workers [11].6 WS, therefore, does not the fishery sector has increasingly marginalized artisanal
affect the incentives of capital owners to invest, fishery and may ultimately lead to its collapse. Over-
which can be seen from the broad modernization of capitalization has resulted in problems related to fishery
the artisanal fleet in the 1980s and 1990s. During the resources. The introduction of trawlers resulted in a drastic
1970s, supportive government policies induced outside decline in the overall catch. The government reacted only
investors to introduce trawlers and trawl nets. This genesis in 1989, when it promulgated a monsoon ban on trawlers.
of capitalist fisheries resulted in decreasing returns As a result of the ban, there was a large jump in output
for the traditional sector, and traditional fishermen realized [12]. A significant part of this increase was for the account
that they needed to adopt new technologies in order to of the motorized artisanal subsector. The artisinal sub-
survive. Hence, they rapidly purchased outboard motors: sector itself, however, also endangers fish resources, as it
during 1981–88, the outboard motor became the major uses potentially destructive fishing techniques like mini-
production unit in Kerala fishery [12]. The 1990s brought trawl nets.
improved thanguvalloms with outboard motors. These The future of the Kerala fishery and of the WS system
rapid developments took place in fishing units practising thus depends on the capability of the sector and the
WS. In some cases, motorization even led to the introduc- government to design and maintain mechanisms to prevent
tion of WS. depletion of fishing resources. The current government
Capital owners are thus indifferent about the WS system, programs for the stimulation of fish culture may prove an
and threats from within the system must come from the important instrument to this respect.
fishermen themselves. Our survey has revealed that they
still favor the system very strongly, not only because of
ethical consideration but also because it means job and References
income security for them personally.
[1] Platteau JP, Baland LM. Income-sharing through work-spreading
arrangements: an economic analysis with special reference to small-
5. Discussion scale fishing. Namur: Faculte des Sciene Economiques et Sociales de
Namur; 1989.
In Kerala, WS is strongly established within the [2] Hayami Y, Kikuchi M. Asian village at the crossroads: an economic
approach to institutional change. Tokyo: University Tokyo Press;
subsector of artisanal fisheries and does not constrain its
1981.
economic development. Fishermen benefit, as it ensures [3] Booth A, Sundrum RM. Labour absorption in agriculture: theore-
them job and income security, while boat owners are tical analysis and empirical investigations. Oxford: Oxford University
indifferent to the system as they pay labor a fixed share of Press; 1985.
the catch. [4] Kurien J, Vijayan AJ. Income spreading mechanisms in common
This does, however, not mean that WS as a system of property resource: karanila system in Kerala’s fishery. Economic and
Political Weekly 1995;30(28).
social security for Kerala fishermen is not under threat. [5] Geertz. Agricultural involution: the process of ecological change in
Increased population pressure in the absence of alternative Indonesia. Berkeley: University of California Press; 1963.
employment may ultimately lead to the break down of the [6] Department of Fisheries, Government of Kerala. Marine Fisheries of
system, when the WS-premium required guaranteeing Kerala – at a glance. 2005 [cited 20-10-2006]; Available from: /http://
www.fisheries.kerala.gov.in/glance.htmS.
employment for everyone becomes insupportably high.
[7] Directorate-of-Fisheries. Techno Socio Economic Survey of
This is what probably caused the decline of shore-seine Fisher folk in Kerala. Government of Kerala: Thiruvanantapuram;
fisheries in Sri Lanka [1]. This type of fishery involves 1990.
[8] SIFFS. A census of the artisanal marine fishing fleet of Kerala 1998.
5
WS among relatives and close friends is for instance practised by Thiruvananthapuram: South Indian Federation of Fishermen Socie-
fishermen on the coast of Senegal [1]. ties; 1999.
6
Traditionally, many share contracts in fisheries involved a type of WS [9] D’Cruz T. The ring seine: evolution and design specifications.
in which both the boat owner and the fishermen shared the cost. The net Thiruvanantapuram: South Indian Federation of Fishermen Socie-
proceeds from the sale of the catch were apportioned into a number of ties; 1998.
fractional shares equal to the number of participating fishermen plus a [10] Directorate-of-Fisheries. Marine fisheries of Kerala at a glance, 1998.
fixed number of shares earmarked for the owner of the craft and gear. This [11] Platteau JP, Nugent JB. Share contracts and their rationale: lessons
system is gradually being replaced by a single-stage sharing system, where from marine fishing. Journal of Development Studies 1992;28(3):
the share allocated to the owner is independent of the number of workers 386–422.
[11] As capital intensity increases, boat owners have more to gain in [12] Rajasenan D. Technology and labour process in marine fishery: the
insulating their income share from variation in crew size and less to lose by Kerala experience. Indian Journal of Labour Economics 2001;
failing to assure access to labor by subsidizing work spreading. 44(2):269–76.

You might also like