You are on page 1of 17

Pricing Equity Swaps in a

Stochastic Interest Rate Economy


MASAAKI
KIJIMAAND YUKIO MUROMACHI

MASAAIU KJJIMA This article considers the pricing ofequity swaps with with conrtant notional principal is also deter-
is on the faculty of constant and variable notional priruipal in a stochas- mined only through the current term struc-
Economics at Kyoto tic interest rate economy. Unlike the deterministic ture of interest rates.
University in Kyoto,
interest rate case, the pricing formulas include COY- This result is counter-intuitive and has
Japan.
relation between interest rates and the equity price puzzled practitioners for many years, since
YWO process, which justifies the practitioners’ belief that equity prices have no impact on the swap rate.
MUROMACHI equity prices a$ect the valuc qf an equity swap by Chance and k c h [1998] show that, in a deter-
is with NL.1 Research some means. ministic interest rate economy, this conclusion
Institute in Tokyo. is true only when the rate is set at the start of
The key tool in derivation ofthqformulas is the-for- the contract. Thus, the puzzle has been
ward-neutral method. The valuation Ofcapped equity resolved in part.
swaps in the stochastic interest economy is also Another question then arises as to
described. whether the equity swap rate, when the rate
is set at the start, is indeed independent of the
swap is an agreement between two equity price process even in the case of vari-

A parties to exchange cash flows in the


future according to a prearranged
formula. The most conmon types of
swaps are interest rate swaps and currency swaps.
Among them, equity swaps are also common
able notional principal. The aim of this article
is to answer this question in a stochastic inter-
est rate economy.
Recall that, in the risk-neutral world, the
instantaneous rate of return of any traded
in a variety of situations for practitioners, where equity is given by the (non-defaultable) spot
party A agrees to pay party I3 cash flows equal interest rate. Also, an equity swap is a transac-
to the return on a stock or equity index for a tion to exchange cash flows equal to the return
number of years and, at the same time, party B on the equity. Hence, the value of the pay-
promises to make either a fixed payment or ments based on the return must be related to
the return on another stock or equity index. See discount bond prices. The equity return also
Bolster, Chance, and Rich [3996] for details of depends on the volatility of the equity price
equity swaps. process, however, as well as the correlation
It is well known that, in the plain vanilla with interest rates. This means that the equity
interest rate swap, the swap rate is determined swap rate should be expected to depend on the
only through the current term structure of equity price process through these parameters.
interest rates (see, e.g., Jarrow and Turnbull We confirm this statement in the case of
[19961). Using the same arbitrage-kee argu- variable notional principal in a stochastic inter-
ment, it can be shown that the equity swap rate est rate economy, thus justifying practitioners’

SUh4MF.R 2001 19
THEJOURNAL OF DERIVATIVES
belief that equity prices affect the value of the equity swap.
We use the stochastic interest rate economy intro- a ( t ,T ) = - 1T
y ( t . u)du. t5T
duced by Amin and Jarrow [1992]. In order to derive
closed-form solutions for the value of equity swaps, we Here, zl(t) and z2(t) denote the standard Wiener pro-
assume that the volatility of interest rates as well as that cesses, assumed to be mutually inde~endent.~ Note that
of the equity price process is deterministic, making our the covariance between the stock price and forward rate
economy Gaussian. Although the interest rates then processes is introduced by the same Wiener process z,(t),
become negative with positive probability, the probabil- which is given by
ity is often neghgble, and the benefit in analpcal tractabil-
ity is considerable. In fact, we can obtain closed-form
solutions for various equity swap rates in the Gaussian
interest rate model.
Our model covers the cases of constant and variable
notional principal, and capped equity swaps and other The time t price of the discount bond maturing at
types of equity swaps considered in Chance and Rich time T is given by
[1998]. It is shown that the equity swap rate with con-
stant notional principal, when setting the rate at the start,
is determined only through the current term structure of
interest rates even in the stochastic interest rate economy,
while it depends on the equity price process in the case
of variable notional principal. Explicit formulas for for- and the spot interest rate is r(t) = f(t,t). The money mar-
ward-start European option prices are obtained, from ket account is defined by
which we can evaluate the value of capped equity swaps
analytically.' Finally, the impact of correlation on the
swap rates is examined through numerical experiments.

I. THE ECONOMY
Hence, the SDEs (1) and (2) suffice to construct our
We consider the stochastic interest rate economy economy.
introduced in Amin and Jarrow [19921. Namely, under the Later, we consider the Gaussian interest rate econ-
risk-neutral probability measure P", the time t price of omy in order to obtain closed-form solutions for various
the risky asset, denoted by S(t),and the instantaneous for- equity swap rates. Although the interest rates become
ward rate at time t for date T, denoted by f(t,T), evolve negative with positive probability, the probability is often
according to the stochastic differential equations: neghglble, and there is a great benefit in analytical tractabil-
ity. Hence, we assume that the ol(t), i = 1, 2, in (1) are
constant (oi(t) oi,say), and that

az(t)d&). t 20
for some deterministic hnction K(t).4 It follows from
and Ito's formula that

( T) +
d l n S ( t ) = r ( t ) - - dt

20 PRICING EQUITYSWAPS IN A STOC'HASTLC INTEKEST RATE


ECONOMY SUMMER 2001
where 0’= ~f + C Y ~and, where In x denotes the natural 11. VALUATION FRAMEWORK
logarithm of x. Also, it is well known (see, e.g., Heath,
Jarrow and Morton [19921) that The forwzp-d-neutral valuation framework seems
particularly usef;l for the pricing of derivatives in the
stochastic interest rate economy. The forward-neutral
method is parallel to the ordinary risk-neutral fi-ame-
work, so we review the risk-neutral method in order to
highlight the basic ideas that the two methods share. In
a(t. T)dq(t). t5T (4) the following, we assume that the current time is 0.
whe e, in this case, a(t, T) = -$(t, T) with P(t, T) =
J,e-tf Wu)duds, t 2 T. The Risk-Neutral Method
Now, according to Inui and fijima [ 19981, this case
reduces to the extended Vasicek model of Hull and White Let C(t) be the time t price of a European deriva-
[ 19901. Namely, the spot rate process is given by tive maturing at time T written on the risky asset S(t). It
is assumed that the derivative is valued by the arbitrage-
free valuation paradigm.
+a 1
i
d r ( t ) = / € ( t ) [ f ( O .t ) - r ( t ) ] &f(0. t ) + $(t) x We consider a self-financing portfolio that consists
of the risky asset S(t) and the money market account
B(0,t). Let e(t)be the number of units of the risky asset
dt + (t) (5)
held in the portfolio, and let b(t) denote the amount in
where the money market account. Then, the value of the port-
folio is given by

+ J’ b(s)dB(O,s) t
C ( t )= C ( 0 )
0

The significance of the extended Vasicek model is


that the model is consistent with the current term struc-
ture of interest rates. Moreover, the time t price of the dis-
count bond maturing at time T is given by The portfolio is said to replicate the European
derivative if
u(0,T )
z(t. T ) = -x
v(0.t ) C ( T )= x

where X is the payoff of the derivative at maturity T.


Under the arbitrage-fi-ee condition, the current price of
the derivative must be equal to C(0).
t5T (7) Let S*(t) denote the relative price ofS(t) with respect
to the money market account B(0, t):

Note that, since K(t) is a deterministic function of


time, both P(t, T) and $(t) are also deterministic hnctions
of time t, so uncertainty in the bond price v(t,T) is due
to the spot interest rate r(t) only.
Other relative prices are defined similarly. Then,
since B*(O, t) = 1 for all t so that dB*(O, t) = 0, we have

SUMMER
2001 21
THEJOURNAL OF DERIVATIVES
C*(t)= C*(O) + J" O(s)dS*(s),
0
t5T

Hence, if S*(t) is a martingale under some proba- Hence, if S,(t) is a martingale under some proba-
bility measure (in fact, it is a martingale under the risk- bility measure, PT, say, the forward price process C,(t) is
neutral measure P"), the relative price process C*(t) is also also a martingale. Denoting the expectations operator
a martingale. Denoting the expectations operator under under PT by E', it follows that
P* by E*, it follows that

= C*(O)= C( 0 )
E*[C*(T)]
whence, since C,(T) = C(T) = X, we obtain
whence, since C*(T) = C(T)/B(O, T) = X/B(O, T), we
obtain C(0)= w(0, T ) E T [ X ]

The probability measure PT is called the forward-


neutral measure, because the forward price process is a
martingale under PT.
This is the basic idea in the risk-neutral valuation Supposing that the risk-neutral measure P* and the
method. forward-neutral measure PTare both found, we thus have
proved the next result, which is a special case of Geman,
The Forward-Neutral Method Karoui, and Rochet [1995].
Theorem 2. Let X be the payoff of a European
In contrast to the risk-neutral method, the forward- derivative security maturing at time T. The price of the
neutral method considers a self-financing portfolio that security at time t is given by
consists of the risky asset S(t) and the discount bond v(t,
T). Let O(t) be the number of units of the risky asset, and
let b(t) denote the number of discount bonds held in the
portfolio. That is, the value of the portfolio is given by

where El and E: denote the conditional expectations


C ( t )= C(0) + / t b ( s ) d t ! ( s .T )+ operators under the risk-neutral measure P* and the for-
0
ward-neutral measure PT,respectively.
We next seek the forward-neutral measure PT in our
Gaussian economy. First, from (3) and (4), we obtain

Other notation and definitions remain the same.


Let S,(t) be the forward price of S(t):

and
Other forward prices are defined similarly. Then,
since v,(t, T) = 1 for all t, we have

22 PRICING EQUIIT SWAPS IN A STOCHASTIC INTEREST R A T E E<ONOMY SUMMER2001


dln vT(t, 7) = pv(t,T ,7 ) d t + zr(t) = zl(t)- / a ( s ,T)ds,
0
t
z;(t) = zz(t) (9)

provided that a(<,’T) f a(t, T), which rules out the deter-
ministic interest rate case. Also, under the fonvard-neu-
T<7 tral measure PT, the forward processes S,(t) and vT(t, Z)
satisfjr the SDEs:
where pS(t,T) = (a’(t, T) - 0’)/2, 0’I Of + 05, and
(t, T, 2) = [a’(t, T) - a”t, T ) I / ~ .It follows fiom Ito’s for-
mula that dST (t)
-- - (01 - a(t. T ) ) d z T ( t )+ -‘

ST ( t )

and

and

These processes are drifiless, so that they are indeed mar-


tingales under PT.
Now, using Ito’s formula, we obtain fiom (10) and
respectively, where ps’(t, T) = a(t, T)(a(t, T) - OJ and (11) that
p’&, T, Z) = a(t, T)[a(t, T) - a(t, T)]. The forward-neu-
trd measure PT is then defined so that z:(t) and zl(t),
ST(t)= ST(0) x

and

are mutually independent, standard Wiener processes.


Notice that the condition (8) is satisfied if the standard a ( s ,T))dzT(s)} , t < T 5 7 (13)
Wiener processes under PT are chosen as
where we define

SUMMER2001 THEJOURNN 23
OF DERIVATIVES
Let us denote the relative price by S*(t) = S(t)/B(O,
t). Then:

= S*(O)= S(O), t 2 0
E,*[S*(t)] (14)

and since the relative price is a martingale under the risk-neu-


tral measure P*. Also, the time t discount bond price with
t maturity T, v(t, T), is given by
&(t1 T ,7) = (a(? 7) - a ( s ,T))2ds, t <T 57

Since a(t, T) is deterministic, and since zr(t) and z,’(t)


are normally distributed with mean 0 and variance t
under PT,both the forward price processes S,(t) and vT(t,
T) are lognormally distributed under PT. Also, S,(T) = Using these results, a similar argument to the one
S(T) and vT(T,T) = v(T, T). Hence, we have a way to eval- given in Jarrow and Turnbull [19961leads to the formu1a:j
uate equity swaps.

111. VALUATION OF EQUITY SWAPS

Equity swaps are classified into two categories, one m

with constant notional principal, and the other with vari-


i= 1
able notional principal. In the former case, the notional
principal is a fixed constant through the life of the con-
tract; in the latter case, it changes according to the refer- which coincides with Equation (1) of Chance and Rich
enced equity price. We derive the valuation formulas for [1998].
equity swaps with constant or variable notional principal If the swap rate is set at the start of the contract, i.e.,
in the Gaussian interest rate economy. to = 0, then we have

Constant Notional Principal 1 - ,U(O.tm)


R=
An equity swap with constant notional principal is
defined as follows: (C 1) A contract starts at time to, to I i= I
0, with an initial notional principal, 1, say; (C2) the pay-
ment dates are ti, 0 < tl < t2 < ..., < tm, with the same since V(0, tm) = 0 by the definition of a swap. Hence, the
notional principal; and (C3) one party pays the return on equity swap rate with constant notional principal is deter-
the underlying equity, S(ti)/S(ti- - 1, and the counter- mined only through the current term structure of inter-
party pays a fixed payment, R, say, at date t,. est rates and is not related to the equity price process.
Sin& the profit/loss at time ti on the fixed side is Notice that we do not assume any volatility struc-
given by S(ti)/S(ti-l)- 1 - R, the risk-neutral method ture to derive this result. In fact, for any interest rate
reveals that the present value of the equity swap (at time economy, the same argument as given in Chance and Rich
0) is given by [1998] can be used to derive the result in (15).

Variable Notional Principal

We consider an equity swap with variable notional


principal defined as follows: (V1) A contract starts at
time to with an initial notional principal, 1, say; (V2) the
payment dates are ti with the notional principal

24 PRICING EQLITY SWAPS IN A STOCHASTIC INTEREST R 4 T E ECONOMY SUMMER


2001
S(ti- l)/S(to)at date ti; and (V3) one party pays the return
on the underlying equity:

we have

and the counterparty pays a fixed payment RS(ti- ,)/S(to)


at date t,. Note the difference between (C3) and (V3).
The different notional principal drives the different pay-
ments over the two swaps.
Under the risk-neutral pricing paradigm, the pre-
sent value of the equity swap on the fixed side is given by
which agrees with the result obtained by Chance and Fbch
[19981.
In order to evaluate the expected values included in
(17), we now assume the Gaussian interest rate economy.
In the forward-neutral valuation framework, we have
from (12) and (13) that

From (14) and the fact that


IT [a1 + a(t, T)- 2a(t,T ) ]drT(t) +

2 2 2
= E,[s*(t7-1)2l(tz-~,ti)],

it follows that
where zT(t), i = 1, 2, are mutually independent, standard
Wiener processes under the forward-neutral measure P'.
O n the other hand, from Theorem 1, we obtain

to 1. 0 (17)

In particular, if the interest rates are deterministic, where c(t, T, Z) is defined by


then, since

SUMMER
2001 25
THEJOURNAL OF DERIVATIVES
for the value of capped equity swaps with constant or vari-
able notional principal in the Gaussian interest rate econ-
omy. Throughout, we denote the cap rate per period by
K, which is a constant over the life of the swap.

Constant Notional Principal


It follows from (17) that the present value of the
equity swap with variable notional principal is given by Since the return, S(ti)/S(ti- -1, is capped by K,
the cash flow at date ti on the fixed side is given by

(1 + R ) ~ f ( O , t l )to, 5 0 (20)
Notice that correlation between the interest rates and
the equity price process is implicit through the term
c(t, T, 2 ) . In fact, ifthe interest rates are deterministic, then where we denote X 3 K + 1. Note that the first term in
and <(t,T, 2) is equal to unity, equation (20) becomes iden- (22) is identical to the cash flow of the equity swap with
tical to (18).Also, if CT, = 0, i.e., the equity price process constant notional principal, while the second term is that
and the interest rates are uncorrelated, then the term of the forward-start European call option with maturity
c(t, T, 2) is a hnction of parameters of interest rates alone. ti, strike price X, and starting date ti-
Finally, we note that various types of equity swaps con- Let us denote the price of the forward-start Euro-
sidered in Chance and Rich [1998] can also be easily eval- ,, ,
pean call option by c(ti- ti, X), 0 Iti- < ti. From The-
uated using (20). orem 1 we obtain
If, in particular, the swap rate is set at the start of the
contract, i.e., to = 0, then we have
c(ti-1, ti, X)= v(0,ti) x

since V’(0, tm) = 0. The swap rate R in this case does Using the forward-neutral method, we have the
depend not only on the current term structure of inter- result as follows (proof is given in Appendix A).
est rates but also on the stock price process, via o1if o1 Theorem 2. In the Gaussian interest rate economy,
f 0, that is,‘-ifthe equity price process is correlated with the price of the forward-start European call option is
the interest rates. given by

IV. VALUATION OF CAPPED EQUITY SWAPS c(t2-1, ti, X) = u ( 0 , ti-l)@(d) -


A capped equity swap is an equityswap with a con-
stant limit on the equity return. Chancd,and Rich [1998]
discuss the pricing of a capped equity swap with constant
notional principal in the deterministic interest rate econ-
omy but they leave the price of forward-start European
call options unspecified. We derive closed-form solutions

26 PRICINGEQUITY SWAP^ IN 4 S T O ~HASTIC INTEREYT


RATE
Ec ONOMY SUMMER2001
where @(x) is the standard normal distribution function Variable Notional Principal
and where
Finally, we consider a capped equity swap with vari-
able notiona1 pridipal. Using the same notation as above,
the cash flow at time tl on the fured side is given by

with
I.-
+RI]-

It should be noted that the parameter C T ~is involved


through 6,in (24).Hence, the equity price process affects
the price of the forward-start European call option, unless
o1= 0.
Now, since Note that the first term in (27) is the cash flow gen-
erated by the equity swap with variable notional princi-
pal, while the second term is that of the forward-start
European call option multiplied by S(ti - ,)/S(t,).
For 0 5 ti - < tl, let

[ S(
E$ S(t,-l)max - {
s ( tt,-1)
z) - x,o}]
we have the result in proposition 1.
Proposition 1. The present value of the capped
equity swap with constant notional principal is given by
The validity of this definition is verified by (27) and
Theorem 1 . Note the difference between (28) and (23).
Using a similar but more complicated argument than
Theorem 2, we have the result in Theorem 3 (proof is
given in Appendix B).
Theorem 3. In the Gaussian interest rate economy,
m the price of the forward-start European call option is
given by6

C’(t&l, ti,X ) = @(d)-


where to I0. If, in particular, the rate is set at the start of
the contract, i.e., to = 0, then the swap rate is determined
by
m

i=l
R= m
where 0%is given in Theorem 2, and where

SUMMER2001 THEJOURNAL OF DERIVATIVES 27


rate is independent of the interest rates in the constant
notional principal case, while it depends on o1through
((t, T, 2) in (19) in the variable notional principal case.
We choose the parameters for the interest rates from
with Inui and Kijima [1998]; that is, we set K(t) = K = 0.05 for
t 2 0, and y = 0.01. The current forward rate curve is set
to be f(0, t) = a + bt + ct2 where a 0.03, b = 0.005,
and c = -0.0002. Note that

Y (1 - e- " ( T - t ) )
a ( t ,T ) = --
6

In order to explain the difference between Theo- Y2


rems 2 and 3, we put Y - lnS(0) in Appendix B. That qqt) = - (1 - P t )
2K
is, we set ti- = 0, so that v(0, ti- = 1 and q(0, ti- 1,
,,
ti) = 0. We then obtain c'(ti- ti, X ) = c(ti- 1, ti, X) in Also, we set o2= 0.2, while 0, is used as a parame-
the two theorems. This means that the difference between ter. All the swaps considered in the examples pay interest
the two cases, constant or variable notional principal, annually, and the initial price of the risky asset is set to be
appears through the hnction ~ ( 0ti,- 1, ti) in Theorem 3. S(0) = 1.
As is shown in Appendix B, the function q(0, ti - ti) ,, Given these parameter values, we first calculate the
expresses the covariance between In S(ti- 1) and In S(ti - term structures of swap rates in the constant and variable
1) / S (ti). notional principal cases using (16) and (22), respectively.
Proposition 2. The present value of the capped The results are shown in Exhibits 1 and 2.
equity swap with variable notional principal is given by In the variable notional principal case, even if the
equity price process and the interest rates are uncorrelated,
i.e., o1= 0, the swap rates are slightly higher than those
b;&IJ. t,, X)= T."(to. t m ) -
in the constant notional principal case. Also, as the value
of o1increases, i.e., the correlation becomes greater, the
swap rates become higher. The dfference in the swap rates
cannot be negligible especially for large t,,, i.e., for equity
m swaps with long maturity.
c ' ( t z - l . t,. X) Next, we calculate the present values of capped equity
1=2
swaps according to Propositions 1 and 3. O f particular
interest are the impacts of the cap rate K, the maturity, and
The swap rate when set at the start of the contract the value of o1on the present values. E h b i t s 3 and 4 depict
is given by the present values for the constant and variable notional
principal cases. The swap rate R is set to be the swap rate
m at time 0, which is shown in Exhibit 1. The other param-
eters are set to be the same as before.
Note that, as the cap rate increases, the present
value of the capped equity swap increases. The increas-
ing rate decreases gradually, however, so that the present
value approaches zero as the cap rate goes to infinite. The
higher the value of CT,,the lower the value of the equity
I

V. NUMERICAL EXAMPLES swap. The effect of C T ~on the value diminishes as the cap
rate increases or the maturity shortens. Although these
Some numerical examples help us investigate the graphs look very similar, the effect of oI on the value in
impact of correlation between interest rates and the equity the variable notional principal case is greater than that in
price process on equity swap rates. Recall that the swap the constant notional principal case.
E X H I B I T1
Swap Rates for Equity Swaps WO)

notional swap maturity (years)


principal 1 CT~ 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
constant 3.30 3.53 3.75 3.95 4.13 4.30 4.46 4.59 4.72 4.83

E X H I B I T2
Term Structures of Swap Rates for Equity Swaps

6.0%
- IS
*-30.0%
5.5% -
-+- -200%
*-10
-10
0%
0.0%
0%
-20.0%
-~ -+- 30.0%

4.0%

3.5%

3.0% . ~ . ~~.
. ..~ ~~.

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Maturity
777cjigure depicts the resu1t.c in Exhibit 1. “IS” mean thc swap rates-for the plain vanilla interest-rate swap, and the rates are equal to those in the constant
notional principal case.

Finally, we calculate the swap rates for capped equity For example, in the case of the constant notional
swaps accordmg to (26) and (30). Exhibits 5 and 6 show principal with tm = 5 and o1= 0.1, if the cap rate is lower
the swap rates for the constant and variable notional prin- than 19.7%,the present value of the capped equity swap is
cipal cases. As the cap rate or the maturity increases, the negative, even for the case that R= 0. It is observed that the
swap rate rises. When the cap rate is too low, the present swap rate rises as o1is reduced in the constant notional prin-
value of a capped equity swap is negative on the tixed side, cipal case (see Exhibit 5), but such a relation fails in the vari-
so that the swap rate becomes negative. able notional principal case when the cap rate is high and
the maturity is long (see Exhibit 6). The dIfZerence between

SUMMER2001 THEJOURNAL OF DERIVATIVES 29


EXHIBIT3
Present Values of Capped Equity Swaps with Constant Notional Principal-Proposition 1

0, i

-0.1

-0.2

-0.3
Q)
0
*= -0.4
n

v
-0.5

-0.6

-0.7
-
-
- ___
sigrnal =O%
srgrnal=O%
sigrnal=O%
---sigrnal=lO%
1

Maturity = 1Oy 1
-
- si rnal=100/
sitmat = l o J
-0.8 1 1

0% 5% 10% 15% 20%

Cap Rate -Swap Rate


The present values are calculated based on Proposition 1. The swap rate R is set to be the swap rate at time 0, which is shown in Exhibit 1. T h e other param-
eters are set to be the same as in Exhibit 2.

EXHIBIT4
Present Values of Capped Equity Swaps with Variable Notional Principal-Proposition 2

0
Maturity = 2y
-0.1

-0.2

-0.3
Q) -0.4
.-0
-0.5
-0.6

-0.7
. _-
.. ..

-0.8

-0.9
... . ... - 1
-1 I 1
0O h 5% 10% 15% 20%

Cap Rate- Swap Rate


77ie present values are calculated based on Proposition 2. 7'he parameters are set to be the same as in Exhibit 3 . Although thefigures look very similar to them
in Exhibit 3, the ejert $0,on the value in the variable notional principal cae is larger tkun that in the constant notional principal case.

30 PRI(:ING EQUITY SWAPS I N .4 STOC:HA>TIC:INTEREST RATE ECONOMY SUMMER moi


E X H I B I T5
Swap Rates for Capped Equity Swaps with Constant Notional Principal-Equation (26)

5.0%

4.0%

a
CI
m 3.0%
w
Q.
m
$ 2.0%
. - -- - --
-+- sigmal =O%
-+- sigmal=O%
+-sigmalEO%
1.O% -
-sigma1=10%
sigrnal=lO%
-sigma~=~~%
- ---

0.0%
0Yo 20% 40% 60% 80% 100%
Cap Rate
The swap rates are calculated based on (26). The parameters are set to be the same as in Exhibit 3 . T h e swap rate increases as 6,decreases.

E X H I B I T6
Swap Rates for Capped Equity Swaps with Variable Notional Principal-Equation (30)

6.0% 1 I

5.0%

4.0%

3.0%

2.0%

1 .O%

0.0%
0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100%
Cap Rate
T h e swap rates are calculated based on (30). The parameters are set to be the same as in Exhibit 4. The suiap rate does not aluiays increase as (T,
decreases in
contrast to Exhibit 5.

SUMMER2001 31
THEJOURNAL OF DERIVATIVES
the two cases comes from c(0, ti - ti) in (30), which
depends on al.

VI. CONCLUDING REMARKS

We have demonstrated valuation of equity swaps


with constant or variable notional principal in a stochas-
tic interest rate economy. Unlike the deterministic inter-
est rate case considered in Chance and Rich [1998], our
pricing formulas include correlation between interest
rates and the equity price process, which justifies the On the other hand, from (5) and (9), we have
practitioners' belief that equity prices affect the value of
an equity swap. The key tool to derive the formulas is the
forward-neutral method.
It is shown that the swap rate for the plain vanilla
equity swap with constant notional principal is deter-
mined only through the term structure of interest rates
in any stochastic interest rate economy, wlde the swap rate O F v ~ t z
with variable notional principal depends on the equity
price process. Dependence of the swap rate on the equity where
price process, the maturity, and the cap rate is examined
through numerical examples, whch reveal that the impact
of stochastic interest rates on equity swaps is considerable.
We assume Gaussian interest rates, so that interest d
rates become negative with positive probability. This may -f(O,
8.5
s) + d(s) + ya(s, t,). s20
be the main limitation of our study. It should be inter-
esting to carry out Monte Carlo simulation experiments
for the pricing of equity swaps in a non-Gaussian inter-
est rate economy.
Another important instrument in equity swaps is the
equity swaption. The valuation of equity swaptions is (A-2)
considered in Chance and k c h [1998] for the deter-
ministic interest rate economy. Although they point out It follows from (A-1) and (A-2) that
that the price of an equity swaption with constant notional
principal is independent of the equity price process, this
property does not hold in our stochastic interest rate set-
ting, and hrther investigation may be necessary to derive
useful results.

A P P E N D I XA
Proof of Theorem 2

First, note that S(tlw1)=Sti(tlT1)v(tl- ,, t,). Hence, using


(7) and (12), we obtain
'.

(A-3)

32 PRICING EQUITY SWAPS I N A STOCHA\TIC INTEREST R A T E ECONOMY SUMMER


1001
Here we have used the fact that

= 0 (A-4
Similarly, by the change of variables U and s, we obtain
whose proof is gk7en below. Now. (A-3) means that x = In
[S(tJ/S(t,- is normally distributed Lvith mean p, and vari-
ance 01. where

and
It follows that

Theorem 2 now follows.


Proof of t(t,
ti - ti) = 0. For simplicity, let t = 0 and
denote which is equal to - @ ( t i ,)P(t,-
- ,,ti), whence the desired result
from (A-5).

APPENDIX
B
Proof of Theorem 3

where

and

From the change of the order of integrations, we obtain:


where C[u, Z ] denotes the covariance between Y and Z .
Non7, using (7), (12), (A-2), and (A-4), we obtain

SUMMER
2001 33
THEJOURNAL OF DEKIVATIVES
E: [f(Z - C [ Y ,Z ] ) ]=

where d' and 0,are defined as in the theorems, completing the


proof.
Lemma. Suppose that (X, Y) is jointly normally dis-
tributed. Then

Since (l3-1) implies that Y is normally distributed with mean


& and variance CT;, where for any f(x) for whch the expectation exists, where C [ x , Y]
denotes the covariance between X and Y.
ProofofLernma. Let <(x, y) be the joint density of (X,
Y) anddefine

Then:
and

Denoting the moment-generating function of (X, Y) by


we obtain ~ ( s t), = Et[esXcrY],
we obtain

Since SX- Y is normally distributed, it follows that


O n the other hand, fiom (A-3) and (B-l), we have

q(s. -1) = exp

= [(O.
1
1
- V [ Y ] - SC[X.Y ]
2

t+1. ti;l - q(0,t t - l . t J

= -V(O, tt-I. t*,l (B-2)

G2 [ X ] }
Hence, (A-3) and (€3-2) together imply that Z - C p , Z ]
+
is normally distributed with mean 1.1, ~ ( 0tl,- tJ and vari-
ance 0;.It follows that

34 PRICING EQUITY SWAP5 IN A sTO('t[A5TlC' INTER€$T RATEECONOMY SUMMER


2001
Recall that the moment-generating function determines REFERENCES
the dstribution uniquely. if it exists. Hence, we conclude that
5x(x)/E[e-y] is a density function of the random variable (X - Amin, K.I., and R.A. Jarrow. “Pricing Options on Risky
C[X, Y]). It follows that Assets in a S t o c k t i c Interest Rate Economy.” Mathematical
Finanre, 2 (1992). pp. 217-238.

Bolster, P., D.M. Chance. and D. Rich. “Executive €quit).


Swaps and Corporate Insider Holding.” Financial Management,
25 (Summer 1996), pp. 14-23.

Chance, D.M., and D. Rich. “The Pricing ofEquity Swaps


completing the proof. and Swaptions.” TlwJoumal of Den’variiles, 5 (Summer 1998),
pp. 19-31.
ENDNOTES Geman, H., N.E. Karoui. and J.C. Rochet. “Change of
‘Chanceand k c h [1998] do not provide pricing formulas Numeraire, Changes of Probability Measure and Option Pric-
for the forward-start European options. ing.”]ounzal $Applied Prol>ability,32 (1995), pp. 443-458.
’In order to guarantee the existence of solutions in the
SDE’s (1) and (2) for the general case, we need to impose some Heath, D., R.A. Jarrow, and A. Morton. “Bond Pricing and
con&tions on the drift and volathties. In our Gaussian case, the Term Structure of Interest Rates: A New Methodology
however, there always exists a unique solution. Also, since a for Contingent Claims Valuation.” Econometrica, 60 (1 992),
rise in the forward rate reduces today’s stock price in practice, pp. 77-105.
we expect a negative correlation between the stock retum and
the forward rate. Hence, it is plausible to assume that either o1 Hull, J., and A. m t e . “Pricing Interest-Rate-Derivative Secu-
in (1) or y in (2) is negative. In either case, the drift term in (2) rities.” Review of Financial Studies, 3 (1990), pp. 573-592.
is positive, which converges to zero as t + T.
“The analysis is vahd even when the Wiener processes Inui, K., and M. Kijima. “A Markovian Framework in Multi-
have a deterministic correlation, i.e., dz,(t)dz,(t)
,- = p(t)dt with
Factor Heath-Jarrow-Morton Models.”Joumal ofFinancia1 and
p(t) a deterministic function of time t. Quantitative Analysis, 33 (1998), pp. 423-440.
4 0 ~results
r can be extended to the case that o1and y are
deterministic functions of time t. Jarrow, R.A., and S . Tumbull. Derivative Securities. Cincinnati:
‘A detailed derivation is available from the authors upon South-Westem Publishing, 1996.
request.
‘Although it is natural to expect that the right-hand side
of (29) is multiplied by v(0, ti - 1), thls is unnecessary because
the cash flow at ti reflects the gross rate ofinterest, S(ti- l)/S(tJ,
up to time ti-l in the variable notional principal case.

SUMMER 2001 35
THFJOURNAL O F DERIVATIVES

You might also like