You are on page 1of 39

Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 18, Number 3—Summer 2004 —Pages 147–172

Are We Consuming Too Much?

Kenneth Arrow, Partha Dasgupta,


Lawrence Goulder, Gretchen Daily, Paul Ehrlich,
Geoffrey Heal, Simon Levin, Karl-Göran Mäler,
Stephen Schneider, David Starrett and
Brian Walker

I s humanity’s use of Earth’s resources endangering the economic possibilities


open to our descendants? There is wide disagreement on the question. Many
people worry about the growth in our use of natural resources over the past
century. Some of this increase reflects the higher resource demands from a growing
world population. But it also reflects the growth of per capita output and consump-
tion. During the twentieth century, world population grew by a factor of four to
more than 6 billion, and industrial output increased by a factor of 40. Per capita

y Kenneth Arrow is Professor of Economics Emeritus, Stanford University, Stanford, Cali-


fornia. Partha Dasgupta is the Frank Ramsey Professor of Economics at the University of
Cambridge and Fellow of St John’s College, both in Cambridge, United Kingdom. Lawrence
Goulder is Professor and Shuzo Nishihara Chair in Environmental and Resource Economics,
Stanford University, Stanford, California. Gretchen Daily is Associate Professor of Biological
Sciences, Stanford University, Stanford, California. Paul Ehrlich is Bing Professor of Popu-
lation Studies, Stanford University, Stanford, California. Geoffrey Heal is Paul Garrett
Professor of Public Policy and Business Responsibility, Columbia Business School, New York,
New York. Simon Levin is Moffett Professor of Biology in the Department of Ecology and
Evolutionary Biology, Princeton University, Princeton, New Jersey. Karl-Göran Mäler is
Director of the Beijer International Institute of Ecological Economics, Stockholm, Sweden.
Stephen Schneider is Professor of Biological Sciences, Stanford University, Stanford, Califor-
nia. David Starrett is Professor of Economics Emeritus, Stanford University, Stanford Cali-
fornia. Brian Walker is a Research Scientist, CSIRO Sustainable Ecosystems Division,
Canberra, Australia. Please address all communications to Kenneth J. Arrow at
具arrow@stanford.edu典.
148 Journal of Economic Perspectives

consumption in industrialized nations today is far higher than it was 100 years ago,
and some would argue that this is irresponsible in the light of its implications for
resource demands. In the last 100 years, energy use has increased by a factor of 16,
annual fish harvesting by a multiple of 35 and carbon and sulfur dioxide emissions
by a factor of 10. The application of nitrogen to the terrestrial environment from
human use of fertilizers, fossil fuels and leguminous crops is now at least as great as
that from all natural sources combined (McNeill, 2000). If we look at specific
resources and services, such as fresh water, the atmosphere as a carbon sink, and a
wide variety of ecosystem services, evidence suggests that continuing growth in their
utilization rates is unsustainable (Vitousek, Ehrlich, Ehrlich and Matson, 1986,
1997; Postel, Daily and Ehrlich, 1996).
On the other hand, it may be claimed that, just as earlier generations invested
in capital goods, research and education to bequeath to current generations the
ability to achieve high levels of consumption, current generations are making the
investments that are necessary to assure higher real living standards in the future,
despite stresses on the natural resource base. Indeed, historical trends in the prices
of marketed natural resources and the recorded growth in conventional indices of
economic progress in currently rich countries suggest resource scarcities have not
bitten as yet (Barnett and Morse, 1963; Johnson, 2000). This optimistic viewpoint
emphasizes the potential of capital accumulation in the form of increased manu-
factured capital and human capital, as well as technological change, to compensate
for the diminishment of natural resources.
This paper, the outgrowth of discussions among a group of ecologists and
economists, offers an analysis that we hope will go some way toward reconciling the
conflicting intuitions. The binocular vision that can be obtained from using both
ecological and economic insights raises questions that might not occur in either
viewpoint alone.
By what criterion should we judge whether consumption is or is not excessive?
Economic analysis has tended to emphasize the criterion of maximizing the present
discounted value of current and future utility from consumption—what we will call
intertemporal social welfare. Current consumption is deemed excessive or deficient
depending on its level relative to that called for by this optimization problem.
However, analysts with a different perspective have applied a criterion of sustain-
ability, which emphasizes the ability of the economy to maintain living standards. In
this paper, we will examine these criteria for evaluating whether consumption is
excessive and identify factors in the economic and ecological domains that deter-
mine whether or not it is in fact so.

Alternative Criteria for the Evaluation of Consumption

In the framework presented here, the underlying elements of intertemporal


social welfare are consumption (broadly defined) and utility. Then the intertem-
poral social welfare V t at time t can be defined as the present discounted value of
Kenneth Arrow et al. 149

the flow of utility from consumption from the present to infinity, discounted using
the constant rate ␦ (⬎ 0).1 In focusing at each moment on aggregate consumption,
our framework abstracts from intratemporal equity issues. The equity issues that
preoccupy us are intertemporal.
One of the determinants of V t is the “productive base,” which consists of
society’s capital assets and institutions at t. The capital assets include manufactured
capital, human capital and natural capital. The productive base also includes the
knowledge base and society’s institutions. Although institutions are frequently
regarded to be capital assets themselves, we will instead view institutions as guiding
the allocation of resources—including capital assets. Institutions include the legal
structure, formal and informal markets, various agencies of government, interper-
sonal networks and the rules and norms that guide their behavior. In what follows,
we will generally employ the term “technology” to refer to both the knowledge base
and the institutions that influence, among other things, the effectiveness with
which this knowledge is put to use. We now discuss two criteria for judging whether
or not current consumption is excessive.

The Maximize Present Value Criterion


One can think of intertemporal social welfare V t as a function of initial
conditions—the capital assets and level of technology at time t—and the choices
from time t forward as to how to allocate output between investment and consump-
tion. According to the maximize present value criterion, actual consumption today is
excessive if it is greater than the level of current consumption prescribed by this
optimal consumption path. To put it another way, current consumption is excessive
if lowering it and increasing investment (or reducing disinvestment) in capital
assets could raise future utility enough to more than compensate (even after
discounting) for the loss in current utility.
The optimal path depends, among other things, on the discount rate, ␦. A
higher value for ␦, other things being equal, means that less weight is placed on
future utility. The “right” value of ␦ has long been a matter of debate. Ramsey
(1928) argued that in a deterministic world the appropriate value of ␦ is zero,
implying that the utility of future people ought to receive the same weight as that

1
Let s and t variously denote time (where s ⱖ t). Let C(s) denote a society’s aggregate consumption
and U(C(s)) the flow of utility at time s. Marginal utility is assumed to be positive. Let V t denote
intertemporal social welfare at time t, defined as the present discounted value of the flow of U(C(s))
from t to infinity, discounted using the constant rate ␦ (⬎ 0). Assuming continuous time, we have

V共t兲 ⫽ 冕s⫽t

U 关C共s兲兴e ⫺␦ 共s⫺t兲 ds.

In calling U “utility,” we are not necessarily subscribing to classical utilitarianism. We are assuming, more
generally, that consumption has a social worth, which we call utility U(C ), and that V t is a numerical
representation of an ethical ordering over infinite utility streams beginning at t. Koopmans (1972) has
identified conditions on orderings that permit one to express V t in the form we are using here.
150 Journal of Economic Perspectives

of people today. Koopmans (1960), however, showed that applying a zero social
rate of pure time preference can lead to paradoxes. Lind (1982) and Portney and
Weyant (1999) contain diverse arguments concerning the appropriate choice of ␦.
One interesting aspect of the optimal consumption path according to the
maximize present value criterion is that it can be linked, theoretically, to the
outcome of a decentralized market economy. In a fully competitive economy with
a complete set of futures markets and no externalities, and in which individuals
discount their future utility at the social rate ␦, the time path of consumption will
correspond to the optimal consumption path. Conversely, in a world where markets
for many future goods and many types of risk bearing do not exist and where
environmental externalities prevail, consumption generally will not be optimal.
Nevertheless, it is possible to conduct social cost-benefit analysis to judge whether
a policy reform at t increases intertemporal social welfare (Dasgupta, 2001a; Arrow,
Dasgupta and Mäler, 2003b).

The Sustainability Criterion


An alternative yardstick for evaluating time profiles of consumption is the
sustainability criterion. The terms “sustainability” and “sustainable development”
became commonplace after the report by the World Commission on Environment
and Development (1987), widely known as the Brundtland Commission (after its
chairperson). Sustainable development was defined as “development that meets
the needs of the present without compromising the ability of future generations to
meet their own needs.” Several interpretations of sustainability are compatible with
this phrase (Pezzey, 1992; Solow, 1992; Heal, 1998; Asheim, 2003). Here we take
sustainability to mean that intertemporal social welfare V must not decrease over
time. Thus, we will say that the sustainability criterion is satisfied at time t if
dV t /dt ⱖ 0.
Several features of this criterion for sustainability deserve emphasis. First, the
criterion concentrates on the change in V, not on V ’s level. Second, even if a
consumption path were to satisfy the criterion today and at all future dates, it would
not guarantee that utility (U ) in each future moment will be as high as it is today
(Asheim, 1994). Third, the criterion does not identify a unique consumption path:
the criterion could in principle be met by many consumption paths. Fourth, if
exhaustible resources are sufficiently important in production and consumption,
then it is conceivable that no sustainable development program exists (Dasgupta
and Heal, 1979, chapter 7). Fifth, satisfying the sustainability criterion today does
not guarantee that the criterion will be satisfied at all future times: a given
consumption path may imply a rising V over the interval from now to the next
period, but a falling V when it is evaluated over some future interval of time. Sixth,
in defining sustainable development, there is no presumption that the consump-
tion path being followed is optimal in the sense of maximizing V. And seventh, a
consumption path that satisfies the sustainability criterion need not be intertem-
porally efficient; an alternative, Pareto-superior path may well exist.
The notion of society’s “productive base” is closely connected to the issue of
Are We Consuming Too Much? 151

whether the sustainability criterion is satisfied. As defined earlier, the productive


base is the stock of all society’s capital assets at t, inclusive of manufactured capital
assets, human capital and natural capital. It also depends on the level of technol-
ogy. For now, we will regard the level of technology as fixed; we will consider
technological change below.
Let genuine investment refer to the change in the productive base. Genuine
investment can be expressed as the sum of the values of investments or disinvest-
ments in each of society’s capital assets, where the value of each investment is the
product of the change in the quantity of the asset times the shadow value or
accounting price of that asset.2 Clearly, intertemporal welfare V(t) is nondecreas-
ing at t if and only if genuine investment is non-negative at t. 3 We can refer to
genuine investment as the change in society’s genuine wealth.
This requirement that the productive base be maintained does not necessarily
entail maintaining any particular set of resources at any given time. Even if some
resources such as stocks of minerals are drawn down along a consumption path, the
sustainability criterion could nevertheless be satisfied if other capital assets were
accumulated sufficiently to offset the resource decline.
While the criterion for sustainable development is straightforward to express,
implementing it poses severe empirical challenges. Measuring changes in quanti-
ties of capital stocks is very difficult. It is especially hard in the case of stocks of
natural resources such as minerals, fossil fuels, fish or insects. In evaluating the
social losses from reductions in natural resources—and thus the alternative invest-
ments necessary to offset such losses— one must consider in principle all of the
contributions of natural resources to present and future utility. Such contributions

2
Let Kt denote the vector of stocks of all capital assets at t. Plainly, V is a function of Kt. In the particular
case where V is stationary (that is, where t itself does not directly influence V ), we can write V t ⫽ V(Kt).
Let K it denote the stock of the i th capital good at date t. By the chain rule of differentiation,

dV/dt ⫽ 冘i
共⭸V/⭸K it 兲共dK it /dt兲 ⫽ 冘
i
p itI it,

where p it (⬅⭸V/⭸K it ) is the shadow price or accounting price of K it , and I it (⬅dK it /dt) denotes the
rate of change in K it . The right-hand side of the expression above is genuine investment.
It is frequently convenient to divide the expression for dV/dt by the value of some one kind of capital
(valued at its shadow price). Thus, if there are just two kinds of capital, denoted, say, by K 1 and K 2 ,
respectively, genuine investment measured relative to the first kind of capital is

共dV/dt兲/共p K1 K 1兲 ⫽ 共1/K 1兲dK 1/dt ⫹ 关p K2 K 2/共p K1 K 1 兲兴共1/K 2 兲共dK 2 /dt兲.

This indicates that our sustainability criterion can be expressed as the growth rate of one kind of capital
plus the product of the growth rate of the other kind of capital and an adjustment factor. Note that, from
the definition of shadow prices above, the adjustment factor is the elasticity of K 1 with respect to K 2
along an isoquant of V(K 1 , K 2 ). We apply this expression in a later section, where we extend the
expression for dV/dt to account for technological change.
3
This result was proved for optimally managed economies by Pearce and Atkinson (1995) and for
arbitrary economies by Dasgupta and Mäler (2000).
152 Journal of Economic Perspectives

may be direct as, say, objects of natural beauty; or they may be indirect, as in the
contributions of ecosystem services such as water purification, flood control, cli-
mate stabilization, pollination of crops, control of agricultural pests and the gen-
eration and maintenance of soil fertility (Daily, 1997); or they may be both (a
wetland). Measuring these services is no easy task.
Another great challenge is determining how much more of one type of capital
asset would be needed to compensate for the loss of one unit of another type of
capital asset. Ecologists express concerns that natural resources have only a limited
set of substitutes. They fear that to the extent that economists are overly optimistic
about opportunities to substitute other capital assets for certain natural resources,
reductions in their stocks would then receive too little weight. A major goal of
ecological economics is to increase our understanding of the ways in which differ-
ent kinds of natural capital contribute to human well-being and the extent to which
they are substitutable for one another and for other kinds of capital assets.4

Extending the Sustainability Criterion to Account for Changing Population


In initial discussion of intertemporal social welfare, V, we have abstracted from
the impact of changes in population size. Dealing with a changing population
presents empirical challenges: forecasting the time profile of population is quite
difficult. But the theoretical issues associated with a changing population may be
even more challenging, as many of the theoretical problems remain unresolved.
Should social welfare seek to maximize the sum of the utilities of all individuals, or
should it seek to maximize some form of average welfare over all people—now and
in the future? How can one compare the social value of a large population with
higher total utility versus a smaller population with higher average utility?
One way to proceed is to regard population as another asset, in addition to the
forms of capital we have already considered. This approach implies that for any
given conception of intertemporal social welfare, there is an accounting price of
population. Under this approach, genuine wealth is the accounting value of all
capital assets, including population. The sustainability criterion continues to re-
quire that genuine wealth at constant accounting prices must not decline, but now
invokes a broader notion of genuine wealth.
Of particular interest is the case where the intertemporal social welfare func-
tion is taken to be the discounted present value of the flow of total utility divided
by the discounted present value of population size over time, where the discount
rate used in both the numerator and denominator is the social rate of pure time

4
On substitutability, see, for example, Dasgupta and Heal (1979, chapter 7), Ehrlich and Ehrlich
(1990), Daily (1997), Daily et al. (2001), Levin (2001), Heal et al. (2001), and Heal (2003). An
important complication related to assessing substitution possibilities is that the potential for substitution
can vary by location. A natural resource in one place, like a local woodland, is not the same economic
commodity as the same natural resource in another place. Dasgupta (1993) discusses the implications
of local nonsubstitutability for the world’s poorest people, who often have no substitutes available to
them when their local resource base is degraded. For an interchange on the relative importance of
substitution possibilities at aggregate and local levels, see Johnson (2001) and Dasgupta (2001b).
Kenneth Arrow et al. 153

preference, ␦. This is a form of “dynamic average utilitarianism.”5 Dasgupta (2001a)


has shown that if dynamic average utilitarianism represents intertemporal social
welfare, then under certain conditions a nondeclining V t is equivalent to the
intuitively appealing requirement that genuine wealth per capita must not decline.
The conditions in question are i) population changes at a constant rate; ii) per
capita consumption is independent of population size (but presumably dependent
on per capita capital assets); and iii) all transformation possibilities among goods
and services exhibit constant returns to scale. We shall make use of this finding
when deriving certain empirical results later in this paper.

Extending the Sustainability Criterion to Account for Technological Change


In the presence of technological change, output and consumption could rise,
and thus intertemporal social welfare V could increase, even if aggregate invest-
ment in terms of manufactured, human and natural capital were negative. How can
we take such changes into account in assessing changes in intertemporal social
welfare, V ?
Here we enter uncharted territory, since there appears to be no prior literature
that makes such a connection. We explore this relationship by examining how total
factor productivity alters the assessment of V. In a rather special model— one with
strong simplifying assumptions—we derive a formula for incorporating total factor
productivity in V. Let ␥ represent the rate of growth of total factor productivity.
␥ is often called the “residual,” since it is what remains after subtracting the
influence of other factors on output growth. Let K (without subscript) represent a
composite of society’s natural, physical and human capital assets.6 Let ␣ be the
elasticity of output with respect to K. Later in the discussion we will observe that
genuine savings rates are close to 0. A straightforward argument shows that with
zero rates of savings, total factor productivity growth at rate ␥ raises the growth rate
of intertemporal social welfare (measured in units of capital) by ␥/␣.7

5
The formula for V in this case is

V共t兲 ⫽ 冕 t

N共s兲U共c共s兲兲e ⫺␦共s⫺t兲ds
冒冕
t

N共s兲e ⫺␦共s⫺t兲ds,

where c(s) and N(s) represent per capita consumption and population size, respectively, at time s.
Notice that, to the extent that the denominator of the above form of V t is not affected by policy, the
maximize present value criterion implies the same optimum no matter whether “total” or “dynamic
average” utilitarianism is adopted as the conception of intertemporal social welfare. However, it matters
hugely whether “total” or “dynamic average” utilitarianism is adopted when one is applying the
sustainability criterion. For further analysis of sustainability under changing population size, see Arrow,
Dasgupta and Mäler (2003a).
6
K can also be regarded as a measure of genuine wealth prior to the adjustment in such wealth to
account for technological change.
7
Assume that K(t), the productive base, is a constant (⫽ K 0 ) and that consumption ⫽ output ⫽ A 0 K 0␣ e rt
for all t. From the definition of V in footnote 2, V is constant when A 0 K 0␣ is constant. Thus, the elasticity
of A 0 (total factor productivity) with respect to K 0 along an isoquant of V is ␣⫺1. In the second equation
154 Journal of Economic Perspectives

Thus, after calculating genuine investment and the associated change in


genuine wealth, one can account for technological change by adding ␥/␣ to the
initially estimated growth rate of genuine wealth. It should be noted that there may
be serious problems with published estimates of total factor productivity and its
growth rate, ␥, because national accounts do not include the economy’s use of
nonmarketed natural and environmental resources. Suppose that over a period of
time, an economy extracts from its natural resource base at an increasing rate.
Then the estimate of total factor productivity growth would be biased upward: some
of the estimated growth in total factor productivity would actually be due to
increased resource use rather than an increase in the knowledge base or improve-
ments in institutional performance. On the other hand, if the rate of natural
resource extraction were falling, recorded growth of total factor productivity would
understate the true contribution of changes in the knowledge base. Our empirical
investigation later in this paper relies on estimates of total factor productivity from
models that do not consider natural resource extraction. Ideally, estimates of the
productivity residual should derive from models that incorporate such extraction.8

Does Satisfying One Criterion Imply that the Other is Satisfied?


The two criteria we have offered for assessing whether consumption is too high
reflect different ethical considerations. An economic program that satisfies the
sustainability criterion need not satisfy the maximize present value criterion. Con-
versely, an economic program that is optimal under the maximize present value
criterion might not satisfy the sustainability criterion.
To see this, suppose that aggregate output is a Cobb-Douglas function of
manufactured capital and the flow of an exhaustible natural resource. (Returns to
scale may be either constant or decreasing.) Solow (1974) showed that sustainable
development is technically feasible if the output elasticity with respect to manufac-
tured capital exceeds the output elasticity with respect to the flow of the natural
resource in production. Dasgupta and Heal (1979) showed, however, that so long
as ␦ ⬎ 0, consumption paths that are optimal in the sense of maximizing intertem-
poral welfare V involve consumption approaching zero in the long run; thus, they
do not yield development that is sustainable over the long term.
The differences between the two criteria have potential implications for public
policy. An investment project that passes the social cost-benefit test (namely, that its
acceptance would increase today’s V ), could result in a decrease in V at some future
date. Therefore, the standard policy remedies for improving economic efficiency—

in footnote 2, substitute the productive base K for what was termed K 1 and total factor productivity A 0
for what was termed K 2 . Since (1/A)(dA/dt) ⫽ ␥ , it follows from this equation that the sustainability
criterion (expressed in terms of K ) is the rate of growth of K plus ␥/␣.
8
In an appendix to this paper available at 具http://www.stanford.edu/⬃goulder典, we derive a formula for
correcting the bias in estimating the rate of growth of total productivity induced by the omission of
resources.
Are We Consuming Too Much? 155

like establishing property rights, addressing externalities and so forth— do not


guarantee sustainability.

Empirical Evidence Relevant to the Maximize Present Value


Criterion

According to the maximize present value criterion, today’s consumption is


excessive if it is higher than the level of current consumption along the consump-
tion path that maximizes the current intertemporal welfare V. No one can seriously
claim to pinpoint the optimal level of current consumption for an actual economy.
However, theoretical considerations can identify factors that would cause current
consumption to be different in a predictable direction from the optimal level.
Relevant theoretical issues include the relationship between market rates of return
on investment and optimal social interest rates on consumption, and the relation-
ship between market prices of contemporaneous goods (including those of current
capital goods) and the social costs of those commodities.

The Market Rate of Return on Investment and the Social Rate of Interest on
Consumption
For a consumption path in a market economy to be socially optimal, the
market rate of return on investment, i, must be equal to the social rate of interest
on consumption, denoted by r. If i exceeds r, markets are biased toward insufficient
saving and excessive current consumption.
It can be shown that, if intertemporal social welfare is given by the form of V
we have postulated here, the social rate of interest on consumption r is given by the
relation r ⫽ ␦ ⫹ ␩ g, where ␦ is the social rate of pure time preference, ␩ is the
elasticity of marginal (social) utility, and g is the rate of growth in aggregate
consumption.9 The parameter ␦ reflects impatience, as is well known. The second
term in the equation, ␩ times g, may require explanation. One can view ␩ as
accounting for the fact that, to the extent that future generations have higher
incomes, their consumption will be higher and the marginal utility of their con-
sumption will be lower. However, ␩ need not simply reflect diminishing marginal
utility of consumption to an individual: it can be interpreted as a social preference
for equality of consumption among generations. Thus, its function can be similar
to the social rate of pure time preference, ␦.
Does i exceed r? One might argue that this cannot be answered from empirical
observation alone, on the grounds that the choices of ␦ and ␩ are inherently value
judgments—subjective matters. However, there exists a different approach that
offers a link to empirical behavior. This approach asserts that a “typical” individual’s
preferences should guide our choices of ␦ and ␩. In particular, it identifies the

9
For one derivation, see Arrow and Kurz (1970). For additional discussion, see Arrow et al. (1996).
156 Journal of Economic Perspectives

social rate of pure time preference, ␦, with the utility discount rate that a typical
individual would endorse. The assumptions of this approach are clearly subject to
debate, but it seems worthwhile to consider what they imply for the relationship
between i and r and thus for the level of consumption.
Several considerations suggest that the typical individual’s preferences regard-
ing the utility discount rate will not be reflected in the market.10 One reason is that,
because of externalities, the utility discount rate that most people would endorse as
socially conscious beings is lower than the rate of time preference emanating from
market transactions. Many years ago, Ramsey, Pigou and Harrod insisted that the
only ethically justifiable value for ␦ is zero. Solow (1974, p. 9) put the matter thus:
“In solemn conclave assembled, so to speak, we ought to act as if the social rate of
(pure) time preference were zero.” A less extreme view would be to say that even
if we don’t treat ␦ as zero, individuals do derive a positive externality (outside of the
marketplace) from the welfare of future generations. An argument combining the
market rate of return on investment with the externality of caring about future
generations might call for “low” values of ␦, in the range, say, of 0 – 0.5 percent per
annum.
What about the other term—␩ g—in the expression for r? If we again base our
choices on a typical individual’s preferences, then ␩ should reflect an average
person’s elasticity of marginal utility of consumption. The value of ␩ is linked to ␴,
the intertemporal elasticity of substitution in consumption: ␩ ⫽ ⫺(␴ ⫺ 1)/␴. Hall’s
(1988) time series estimates of ␴ suggest that plausible values for ␩ might lie in the
range of 2– 4. If we assume per capita growth rates in consumption ( g) to have been
of the order of 1.5 percent per annum, we arrive at 3 to 6 percent per annum for the
term ␩g. Together, these considerations would tentatively suggest a value for r in
the range 3.0 – 6.5 percent per annum.
How does this value compare with the market rate of return on investment i?
We need to choose an appropriate market interest rate with which to make the
comparison, but rates of return on different securities vary considerably. The real
rate of return on private capital in the United States (as directed for use in
government project analysis, United States Office of Management and Budget,
1992) is 7.0 percent; on equities from 1970 –2000, 7.4 percent; but on Treasury bills
from 1970 –2000, just 1.6 percent. (The last two figures are derived by computation
from the Wharton-Data Resources website.) We want to compare the social rate of
interest on consumption r with a risk-free rate. If one interprets Treasury bills as the
risk-free asset, then the market rate seems as low or lower than the value for r we

10
Hence, the justification for a “lower” ␦ may remain, despite the fact that equilibrium outcomes from
individuals’ market behavior at first blush suggests a higher ␦. On this, see Marglin (1963), Lind (1964)
and Sen (1967). In discussing this issue, we have just referred to an externality related to individuals’
concerns for future generations’ well-being. Elsewhere in this paper, we refer to externalities associated
with the use of natural resources. One could interpret individuals’ inefficient (excessively rapid)
exploitation of natural resources as evidence that they care little about future welfare. However, we
prefer the interpretation that such externalities make it impossible for individuals to express their
concerns about the future in their individual production or consumption decisions.
Kenneth Arrow et al. 157

calculated above. Thus, this rough comparison provides little support for the
argument that consumption is excessive.
Two other pieces of evidence that market rates of return on investment may
exceed the social rate of interest on consumption come from the incompleteness
of markets and the existence of capital taxes. The absence of a complete set of
risk-bearing markets, for example, implies that risks cannot be pooled perfectly.
Returns from investment are therefore more uncertain, and so recipients (savers)
would be expected to attach a lower value to investments than they would have if
risks had been pooled more effectively. Consequently, the rate of saving is lower.
The absence of complete pooling tends to promote excessive consumption.
Similarly, the taxation of capital income lowers the private return on capital
below the social return and thus discourages saving and promotes excessive con-
sumption. However, the normative impacts of capital income taxation depend on
other taxes and the prices of various inputs to consumption goods. Labor taxes can
discourage labor supply and reduce wage incomes, thus causing current consump-
tion to fall short of the optimal level despite the influence of capital taxes.
Moreover, the level of current consumption depends importantly on the prices of
the inputs used to produce consumption goods. The pricing of natural resource
inputs seems especially important, as we discuss in the following section.

Underpricing of Natural Resources Relative to Social Cost


The level of consumption depends not only on market interest rates, but also
on the price of current consumption relative to its social cost or, more specifically,
the price of consumption goods relative to capital goods. To the extent that
consumption goods are priced below their social cost, consumption will tend to be
excessive.
Some natural resources are consumption goods, others are direct or indirect
inputs in the production of consumption goods, and many are both. The under-
pricing of natural resources may contribute to the pricing of consumption goods
below their social cost. Such underpricing also alters the relative prices of different
consumption goods, thereby leading to inefficiencies in the composition (as well as
overall level) of consumption: too much consumption of resource-intensive goods
and services relative to consumption of other goods. Thus, when natural resource
inputs are priced below social cost, both the overall level and the composition of
consumption can be affected in ways that lead to excessive natural resource use.
The underpricing of natural resources can stem from at least three sources.
First, insecure or poorly defined property rights can lead to excessively rapid
resource exploitation if the exploitation does not require much prior investment
(Bohn and Deacon, 2000). Second, natural resource underpricing can arise from
the failure of the market to incorporate the (negative) externalities associated with
the use of natural resources. Examples of such externalities include the various
damages stemming from the use of fossil fuels (such as acid precipitation or climate
change), and the loss of such ecosystem services as flood control, water-filtration
and habitat provision when wetlands are drained for conversion to farms.
158 Journal of Economic Perspectives

Third, use of natural resources may be underpriced because of government


subsidies. The World Bank’s 1992 World Development Report (Figure 3.2) examined
fossil fuel, electricity and water prices in 32 developing countries. In all but three
of those countries, subsidies caused prices to fall below cost, even before account-
ing for potential externalities. Similarly, the International Energy Agency (1999)
has estimated that in India, China and the Russian Federation, full-cost pricing
would reduce energy consumption by 7, 9 and 16 percent, respectively. In these
countries, most of the departure from social cost pricing is attributed to energy
subsidies. For estimates of aggregate global subsidies on the use of environmental
and natural resources, see Myers and Kent (2000).
The influence of OPEC on the international market for oil could function as
a counterbalance to the above arguments, potentially raising world oil prices up to
or beyond social cost. However, there is as yet no clear consensus as to whether
current world prices are above or below social cost. In addition, the pricing of oil
might well be the exception to a more general pattern of underpriced natural
resources.
The underpricing of natural resource inputs can also reduce the prices of
investment goods. If such underpricing is especially pronounced for investment
goods, it could promote a higher ratio of investment to consumption. This does not
undo the problem of excessive use of natural resources, which is a more funda-
mental concern. If the natural resource inputs in the production of investment
goods are underpriced, the rates of depletion of natural resources will be too rapid.
The rate of accumulation of manufactured capital may or may not exceed the
optimal rate, but genuine investment—that is, overall investment, inclusive of
changes in stocks of natural capital—is likely to be insufficient because of the
underpricing of natural resources and the associated excessively rapid depletion of
these resources.

Interdependence in Consumption
Interdependence in consumption can also lead to prices of consumption
below social cost. Building on Veblen (1899) and Duesenberry (1949), a small but
growing body of empirical work (for example, Frank, 1985a, b; Ng, 1987; Howarth,
1996; Schor, 1998) suggests that a person’s sense of well-being is based not only on
a person’s own consumption, but also on the person’s consumption relative to a
“reference group.” When others’ consumption rises in comparison, an individual
could suffer from a loss of well-being because that person’s relative consumption
now falls. This interdependence in consumption can be viewed as an externality,
which can compel individuals to work harder and consume more to keep up with
neighbors. It is individually rational behavior, but collectively suboptimal. A formal
“growth model” incorporating these ideas has been developed by Cooper, Garcia-
Peñalosa and Funk (2001).
However, interdependence in consumption does not necessarily imply that
people consume excessively. Suppose that the “relative consumption effect” applies
not only to current consumption, but also to future consumption (and to leisure,
Are We Consuming Too Much? 159

including sleep). Working harder and consuming more today would then improve
one’s relative current consumption, but worsen one’s relative current “consump-
tion” of leisure and also one’s relative future consumption! Thus, the bias from
interdependence depends on the strength of the effects along various margins. If
the effect on individual well-being of relative consumption is symmetric, operating
equally on relative consumption and relative leisure now and in the future, it may
have no impact on current behavior relative to what would occur if this effect were
absent. In this case, the relative consumption effect operates like a lump-sum tax,
reducing a person’s sense of well-being without changing that person’s allocation
of labor resources or income.

General Findings
We have identified several factors influencing consumption and have shown
how they enable us to judge whether consumption is excessive according to the
maximize present value criterion. Several factors—the inability to pool risks per-
fectly, the taxation of capital income and the underpricing of natural resources—
contribute toward excessive consumption. (Below, we will observe that these same
factors also work toward excessive consumption according to the sustainability
criterion.) Among these imperfections, the underpricing of natural resources
strikes us as the most transparent.

Empirical Evidence Relevant to the Sustainability Criterion

A First Step: Measuring Genuine Investment


As mentioned, genuine investment at date t is the sum of the values of changes
in capital stocks at t, evaluated at their accounting prices. It is the change in
genuine wealth at constant accounting prices. The assets to be included are
manufactured capital, human capital, natural capital and the knowledge base
(Dasgupta and Mäler, 2000; Arrow, Dasgupta and Mäler, 2003b). In this subsection,
we begin evaluating whether various nations are meeting the sustainability require-
ment by estimating and observing the sign of genuine investment. In the next
subsection, we will extend the analysis to account for changes in population and
technological change.
A growing body of research now aims to measure genuine investment in
various countries. The lead has been taken by Kirk Hamilton and his collaborators
at the World Bank (for example, Pearce, Hamilton and Atkinson, 1996; Hamilton
and Clemens, 1999; Hamilton, 2000, 2002). Hamilton and Clemens (1999), in
particular, offered estimates of genuine investment for nearly every nation for the
year 1998. They estimated genuine investment by first adding net investment in
human capital to existing country-level estimates of investment in manufactured
160 Journal of Economic Perspectives

capital. They then made a further adjustment to account for disinvestment in


natural resources and environmental capital.11
To estimate the accumulation of manufactured capital, Hamilton and Clemens
(1999) used figures for net national saving. To estimate the accumulation of human
capital, they used expenditure on education. To account for disinvestments in
natural resources and environmental capital, they considered the net changes in
the stocks of commercial forests, oil and minerals and in the quality of the
atmosphere in terms of its carbon dioxide content.12
Interestingly, the authors found that in 1998, genuine investment was positive
in all the rich nations of the world and in many of the poorer nations as well.
However, for 33 of the world’s poor countries, including many of the nations of
north Africa and sub-Saharan Africa, they estimated that genuine investment was
negative.
Here we adopt the Hamilton-Clemens approach as a starting point for evalu-
ating whether selected nations and regions meet the sustainability criterion. Rather
than calculate the figures for a single year (as in Hamilton-Clemens), we have
calculated annual averages over the past three decades, using annual data from the
World Development Indicators published in the World Bank’s website at 具http://
devdata.worldbank.org/dataonline典. We present our estimates in Table 1. The
table includes poor nations (China, nations in the Indian subcontinent and nations
in the sub-Saharan Africa region), oil-exporting countries (in the Middle East/
North Africa region) and industrialized nations (the United States and the United
Kingdom).
The differences between genuine investment and the standard measure, net
domestic investment, are particularly striking for the Middle East/North Africa and
sub-Saharan Africa regions. In these regions, the loss of natural resources more
than offset the accumulation of manufactured capital (as reflected in domestic net
investment) and human capital (as reflected in expenditure on education). For the
United States and the United Kingdom, estimated genuine investment exceeded
domestic net investment, since the increase in human capital exceeded the value of
natural resource depletion.
These figures give an initial glimpse of the change in V. We will shortly
consider how the picture is altered when changes in technology and in population
are taken into account. Before doing so, however, it is useful to consider potential

11
Hamilton and Clemens (1999) employ the term “genuine domestic saving,” which we treat as
synonymous with genuine investment. The two cannot be distinguished from the data employed in their
study, because the data do not include international capital flows.
12
In calculating the reduction in natural resource stocks, Hamilton and Clemens do not include
discoveries of new reserves as an offsetting element. As an accounting matter this seems correct. It is
consistent with the notion that the overall global stock of mineral or fuel resources is given—that
devoting resources toward exploration, and the subsequent discovery of previously unknown reserves,
does not constitute an enlargement of the stock. At the same time, expenditure on exploration
equipment or structures should constitute a positive investment in physical capital.
Kenneth Arrow et al. 161

Table 1
Genuine Investment and Components as Percentage of GDP

Natural Resource Depletion

Domestic net Education Damage from Energy Mineral Net forest Genuine
Country investment expenditure CO2 emissions depletion depletion depletion investment

Bangladesh 7.89 1.53 0.25 0.61 0.00 1.41 7.14


1973–2001
India 11.74 3.29 1.17 2.89 0.46 1.05 9.47
1970–2001
Nepal 14.82 2.65 0.20 0.00 0.30 3.67 13.31
1970–2001
Pakistan 10.92 2.02 0.75 2.60 0.00 0.84 8.75
1970–2001
China 30.06 1.96 2.48 6.11 0.50 0.22 22.72
1982–2001 (without 1994)
Sub-Saharan Africa 3.49 4.78 0.81 7.31 1.71 0.52 ⫺2.09
1974–82; 1986–2001
Middle East & North Africa 14.72 4.70 0.80 25.54 0.12 0.06 ⫺7.09
1976–89; 1991–2001
United Kingdom 3.70 5.21 0.32 1.20 0.00 0.00 7.38
1971–2001
United States 5.73 5.62 0.42 1.95 0.05 0.00 8.94
1970–2001

Source: Authors’ calculations, using data from World Bank (2003).

biases in the estimation of genuine investment.13 First, as Hamilton and Clemens


emphasize, one serious problem is the lack of comprehensive data in national
accounts. For many important (and declining) natural resource stocks, data are not
available—at least not for every country. Among the natural resources not included
in the Hamilton-Clemens study are water resources, forests as agents of carbon
sequestration, fisheries, air and water pollutants, soil and biodiversity. So there is an
undercount, possibly a serious one.
Second, these estimates (as well as earlier estimates by Hamilton and Clemens)
employ market prices in indicating potential trade-offs among different forms of
capital. To the extent that natural capital is typically underpriced, the use of market
prices could bias the estimate of genuine investment in an upward direction.
Third, these estimates consider only very broad categories of capital. At a high
level of aggregation, one can miss critical bottlenecks that impose limits on substi-
tution possibilities. The rural poor in the world’s poorest countries, for example,
often cannot find substitutes when their water holes vanish and the local woodlands
recede (Dasgupta, 1993). Aggregated calculations can easily miss these details and
underestimate the accounting prices of local resource bases.
Fourth, in these calculations, disinvestment in environmental capital is calcu-

13
For a more extensive discussion of ways in which genuine investment could be better estimated, see
Arrow, Dasgupta and Mäler (2003b).
162 Journal of Economic Perspectives

lated simply as the estimated damage associated with annual emissions of carbon
dioxide. A ton of carbon dioxide emission is assumed to lead to a loss of $20 (U.S.)
of environmental capital. However, to the extent that newly manufactured capital
is expected to yield increased carbon dioxide emissions and thereby inflict
subsequent damage, the value of investment in manufactured capital is reduced.14
The Hamilton-Clemens approach adopted here ignores this effect. A further
problem is that this approach implicitly links all of the damage from carbon dioxide
emissions to the country responsible for the emissions, whereas in fact a given
country’s emissions of carbon dioxide produce climate impacts worldwide.
Set against these considerations is another issue that is ambiguous in its effect.
The proxy for increases in human capital— expenditure on education—neglects
depreciation of human capital due to morbidity, mortality and retirement from the
workforce. In this respect, it overstates the increase in human capital. On the other
hand, this proxy ignores skills gained through channels other than formal educa-
tion, as well as improvements in human productivity that are due to expenditures
on health and nutrition. This implies the opposite bias.
While the measure of genuine investment in Table 1 conveys useful informa-
tion, it does not consider changes in population or technology. If population grows
fast enough, the long-run productive base per person could decline even if genuine
investment were positive. On the other hand, accounting for improvements in
productivity would likely brighten the picture. In what follows, we extend our
empirical assessment to consider the impacts of population growth and changes in
total factor productivity.

Population Growth, Technological Change and Sustainability


The first column in Table 2 reproduces the figures from the last column of
Table 1, which are estimates of average genuine investment as a proportion of GDP
over the interval 1970 –2001. The second column is an initial, unadjusted estimate
of the growth rate of genuine wealth. We arrive at this column by multiplying the
numbers in the first column by a presumed GDP/wealth ratio for the country or
region in question—the assumed average GDP/wealth ratio over the three-decade
interval. Published estimates of GDP-wealth (or “output/wealth”) ratios tradition-
ally have been taken to be something like 0.20 – 0.30 per year. However, a wide array
of capital assets like human capital and many types of natural capital are missing
from national accounts. To offset this bias, Table 2 uses the figure 0.15 per year for
poor and oil-rich countries and regions and 0.20 per year for industrialized coun-
tries. Let W refer to per capita genuine wealth. We arrive at the growth rate of W

14
This does not double count. In today’s genuine investment calculation, today’s emissions of CO2
constitute a reduction in “climate-system capital.” This negative investment is the present value of the
damages associated with these current emissions. At the same time, the value of today’s investments in
manufactured capital should be the present value of the net services associated with these manufactured
assets. Future emissions and climate damages associated with these assets reduce these net service
streams and imply a reduction in the value of current investment in these assets.
Are We Consuming Too Much? 163

Table 2
Growth Rates of Per Capita Genuine Wealth

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)


Growth Rate of Growth Rate of
Genuine Per Capita Per Capita Growth
Investment Growth Rate Population Genuine TFP Genuine Rate of
as Percent of Unadjusted Growth Wealth—before Growth Wealth—after per capita
Country of GDP Genuine Wealth Rate TFP Adjustment Rate TFP Adjustment GDP

Bangladesh 7.14 1.07 2.16 ⫺1.09 0.81 0.30 1.88


India 9.47 1.42 1.99 ⫺0.57 0.64 0.54 2.96
Nepal 13.31 2.00 2.24 ⫺0.24 0.51 0.63 1.86
Pakistan 8.75 1.31 2.66 ⫺1.35 1.13 0.59 2.21
China 22.72 3.41 1.35 2.06 3.64 8.33 7.77
Sub-Saharan
Africa ⫺2.09 ⫺0.31 2.74 ⫺3.05 0.28 ⫺2.58 ⫺0.01
Middle East/
North Africa ⫺7.09 ⫺1.06 2.37 ⫺3.43 ⫺0.23 ⫺3.82 0.74
United Kingdom 7.38 1.48 0.18 1.30 0.58 2.29 2.19
United States 8.94 1.79 1.07 0.72 0.02 0.75 1.99

Note: These calculations employ the following parameters: output-capital ratio, poor countries/regions
0.15; output-capital ratio, rich countries 0.20; ␣ (share of human and reproducible capital in output)
0.58.
Data for genuine investment, population growth, and GDP growth derive from the World Bank (2003).
The genuine investment percentages of GDP derive from data over the time-intervals indicated in Table
1. The population growth rate is the average rate over the period 1970 –2000.
The estimate for China’s total factor productivity (TFP) growth is from Collins and Bosworth (1996). For
all other countries or regions, the estimates are from Klenow and Rodriguez-Clare (1997).

(column 4) by subtracting the population growth rate (column 3) from the growth
rate of genuine wealth.
Column 4’s figures for changes in per capita genuine wealth do not account
for technological change. The remaining adjustments in the table are intended to
account for such change as measured through changes in total factor productivity.
Column 5 offers estimates of the growth of the total factor productivity residual, as
reported for the period 1970 –2000 in Klenow and Rodrı́guez-Clare (1997).15 For
the Middle East/North Africa and Sub-Saharan Africa regions, we obtain the
residual by taking a weighted average of the estimates for the countries within each
region, using GDP as weights. In the case of China, we report estimates from Collins
and Bosworth (1996) for a comparable period, since Klenow and Rodrı́guez-Clare
did not offer estimates for this country. The residual was negative only in the
Middle East/North Africa region.
We use the numbers in column 5 to arrive at an estimate of the change in per
capita genuine wealth that accounts for the impact of projected technological

15
Klenow and Rodrı́guez-Clare report the growth rates of a transform of total factor productivity. From
this information we calculate the associated growth rate of total productivity.
164 Journal of Economic Perspectives

change. Here we employ the approximation formula referred to earlier (and


derived in footnote 7). The formula asserts that the contribution of total factor
productivity growth to movements in intertemporal social welfare expressed in
units of overall capital—that is, the contribution to movements in V/( p K K )—is
␥/␣*, where ␥ is the growth rate of the total factor productivity residual and ␣* is
the elasticity of output with respect to all (manufactured, human and natural)
capital. ␣* can be calculated as the sum of the exponents of each of the types of
capital in the aggregate production function. Ideally, one would want to calculate
␣* from a production function that includes natural capital. However, we do not
have estimates from such a production function. Instead, we rely on the aggregate
production function estimated by Klenow and Rodrı́guez-Clare (1997), which
includes human and manufactured capital only. The exponents on these two types
of capital are 0.30 and 0.28, respectively. This implies ␣* ⫽ 0.58 and suggests that
the adjustment for total factor productivity growth is 1.72 times the value in column
5 of Table 2. This is added to column 4 to yield column 6, our adjusted estimate of
the growth rate of W (per capita genuine wealth), which takes account of total
factor productivity growth.
This adjustment may well overstate the contribution of total factor productivity
growth, for two reasons. First, the omission of natural capital biases downward the
estimate of ␣* and thus biases upward the total factor productivity adjustment,
␥/␣*. Suppose that in the true aggregate production function, natural capital’s
share or exponent were 10 percent, and the shares of human and reproducible
capital were therefore 10 percent lower than indicated above (to preserve constant
returns). In this case, ␣* would be 0.62 and the adjustment would be 1.61 (rather
than 1.72) times the value in column 5. Moreover, as mentioned earlier, the neglect
of natural capital in the production function implies that ␥ will be misestimated,
with the direction of the error depending on the difference in the growth rates of
natural resource extraction and overall output. We find that growth rates of energy
extraction (a potential proxy for natural resource extraction) tend to exceed GDP
growth rates over the past three decades, which implies an upward bias in the
estimate of ␥. Thus, both ␥ and ␣* may be misestimated in a way that leads to an
exaggeration of the impact of technological change. In future work, we hope to
arrive at improved estimates of the adjustment factor ␥/␣*. However, for the
present paper we employ in Table 2 the values that emerge directly from the
Klenow and Rodrı́guez-Clare (1997) estimates, which appear to be the most satis-
factory estimates currently available.

The Poor World


Our (rather tentative) estimates in Table 2 suggest that parts of the poor world
and some oil exporting regions are not meeting the sustainability criterion. Popu-
lation growth implies significant differences between the initially estimated growth
rate of genuine wealth (column 2) and the growth rate on a per capita basis
(column 4). And the results in column 6, which account for both population
Kenneth Arrow et al. 165

growth and technological change, differ significantly from the original genuine
investment calculations.
Pakistan, Bangladesh, India and Nepal show positive values for the growth rate
of W. However, estimated growth rates for per capita genuine wealth are projected
to be negative in the Sub-Saharan Africa and Middle East/North Africa regions. At
an annual rate of decline of 2.6 percent in genuine wealth per annum, the average
person in the sub-Saharan Africa region becomes poorer by a factor of two about
every 25 years. The ills of sub-Saharan Africa are routine reading in today’s
newspapers and magazines. But they are not depicted in terms of a decline in
wealth.
In the Middle East/North Africa region, per capita genuine wealth is
estimated to be declining at an annual rate of 3.8 percent, after adjusting for
technological change. For this region, the estimate for the growth rate in total
factor productivity is negative (⫺0.23 percent). Hence, adjusting for techno-
logical change for this region further increases the estimated decline of per
capita genuine wealth. It is worth noting that the negative estimate for total
factor productivity growth depends closely on the value one attaches to ex-
tracted energy resources. Alternative assumptions about future energy prices
can significantly influence this valuation and the estimate of total factor pro-
ductivity. Thus, the uncertainties in the estimates are especially great in the case
of the Middle East/North Africa region.
The results for China are strikingly different from those just discussed. The
unadjusted growth rate of per capita genuine wealth is significantly positive—about
2.1 percent. The estimated growth rate of total factor productivity (3.6 percent) is
high compared with the other countries examined, helping to augment the growth
rate of W. However, China’s figure could be biased upward: the estimates of
genuine investment do not include soil erosion or urban pollution, both of which
are thought by experts to be especially problematic in China.
How do changes in wealth per head compare with changes in conventional
measures of economic progress? The far-right column of Table 2 contains estimates
of the rate of change of GDP per head over the interval 1970 –2000. In all of the
listed countries except for China, the growth rate of per capita GDP is considerably
higher than the estimated growth rate of per capita genuine wealth. In the Middle
East/North Africa Region, per capita GDP growth is positive, while per capita
genuine wealth is falling. For all of these countries except China, an assessment of
long-term economic development would be significantly off the mark if it were to
look at growth rates in GDP per head.
One might infer from the table that several poor countries are “consum-
ing too much.” Such a conclusion would be off the mark. In many poor
nations, the production of both capital goods and consumption goods is
highly inefficient. The countries simultaneously suffer from low levels of
genuine investment and consumption, and in the most important sense of
the term, these nations do not overconsume. One cannot assure a satisfac-
tory quality of life in these nations simply by devoting a larger share of
166 Journal of Economic Perspectives

productive factors toward the production of capital goods. Indeed, devoting a


greater share of output toward investment could cause considerable misery by
reducing what is already a very low level of per capita consumption. For these
nations, the sustainability problem is part of a larger problem of inefficient
production and low productivity, which accounts for both low genuine invest-
ment and low consumption.

The Rich World


Table 2 also displayed estimated growth rates of W for the United States and
the United Kingdom. These are positive for both countries, although the U.S.
estimate is about a third of the UK estimate. The estimates of growth rates of per
capita GDP are also positive. Thus, for these countries, the differences across the
two indices of economic development are less dramatic.
One might be tempted to conclude that the rich countries are avoiding
consuming too much. But it is important to note that the figures for changes in
per capita wealth for different countries are not entirely independent. The
“success” of rich countries may in part be due to the “failure” of poorer nations.
As we noted earlier, natural capital is very frequently underpriced in the market
because property rights may be poorly defined or poorly enforced. In extreme
cases, such capital assets are free. Dasgupta (1990) and Chichilnisky (1994) have
used this fact to argue that countries that are exporting resource-based products
(they are often among the poorest) are to an extent subsidizing the consump-
tion of those countries that are importing these products (they are often among
the richest). Such hidden subsidies would help promote positive growth rates in
per capita wealth in rich countries, while working toward reduced growth rates
in the poorer nations that export resource-based products. High levels of
consumption in rich countries may promote excessive resource degradation in
poor countries, which imperils well-being in the poorer countries. This negative
by-product of rich nations’ consumption is not captured in existing measures of
changes in per capita wealth.

Sensitivity of Results to the Assumed GDP-Wealth Ratio


One significant parameter used in our estimates of the growth of W is the
GDP-wealth ratio. This parameter is employed to translate genuine investment into
a growth rate of (unadjusted) genuine wealth. Table 3 indicates the sensitivity of
our estimates to this ratio. The middle column reproduces the results in Table 2 on
the growth rate of per capita annual wealth. The left and right columns, respec-
tively, consider a lower and higher value for the GDP-wealth ratio. For countries
with positive genuine investment, a lower value for this ratio implies a higher
beginning-of-period level of wealth; thus, for a given level of genuine investment, it
implies a lower growth of adjusted per capita genuine wealth. For the regions with
negative genuine investment (the Sub-Saharan Africa and Middle East/North
Africa regions), a lower value implies a higher (that is, less negative) growth rate of
Are We Consuming Too Much? 167

Table 3
Sensitivity Analysis

GDP-wealth Central GDP-wealth


Country ratio ⫽ 0.10 case ratio ⫽ 0.25

Bangladesh ⫺0.15 0.30 0.93


India ⫺0.01 0.54 1.41
Nepal ⫺0.09 0.63 1.91
Pakistan 0.03 0.59 1.34
China 6.79 8.33 10.20
Sub-Saharan Africa ⫺2.50 ⫺2.58 ⫺2.82
Middle East/North Africa ⫺3.44 ⫺3.82 ⫺4.51
United Kingdom 1.49 2.29 2.59
United States ⫺0.15 0.75 1.19

genuine wealth. Results seem fairly sensitive to this parameter. When the output-
wealth ratio is 0.10, the estimated growth of W becomes negative in Bangladesh,
India, Nepal and the United States.
In the light of the sensitivity of these results to this parameter—as well as
significant uncertainties about the underlying data and other parameters that
enter these calculations— our conclusions must be very tentative. But despite
the uncertainties, it seems clear that measures of changes in per capita genuine
wealth yield a very different—and often much bleaker—picture of the prospects
for poor nations, as compared with the message implied by changes in GDP per
capita.

Further Perspectives and Conclusions

We have evaluated consumption levels according to two criteria: the dis-


counted present value of the utility stream (the maximize present value criterion)
and the maintenance or improvement of intertemporal social welfare (the sustain-
ability criterion). Although the evidence is far from conclusive, we find some
support for the view that consumption’s share of output is likely to be higher than
that which is prescribed by the maximize present value criterion. We also find
evidence that several nations of the globe are failing to meet a sustainability
criterion: their investments in human and manufactured capital are not sufficient
to offset the depletion of natural capital. This investment problem seems most
acute in some of the poorest countries of the world.
We would emphasize that insufficient investment by poor countries does not
imply excessive consumption in the most important sense. For many of the poorest
nations of the world, where productivity and real incomes are low, both consump-
tion and investment are inadequate: current consumption does not yield a decent
168 Journal of Economic Perspectives

living standard for the present generation, and current investment does not assure
a higher (or even the same) standard for future generations.
This study and all previous studies of which we are aware provide only point
estimates of genuine investment or of changes in genuine wealth. Given the vast
uncertainties associated with the estimates, even when point estimates are positive,
there may remain a significant possibility that genuine investment is negative. The
uncertainties justify added caution.
The presence of nonlinearities compounds the importance of uncertainty.
The biophysical impacts associated with the loss of natural capital can be highly
nonlinear: these impacts may be small over a considerable range, and then
become immense once a critical threshold is reached. Crossing the threshold
leads to a “bifurcation,” a situation where the characteristics of the natural
system change fundamentally. For example, shallow clear fresh water lakes can
absorb a low level of phosphorus with little ill effect. However, if more phos-
phorus is added to the lake through sewage or runoff from agricultural land,
more algae grows in the water, less sunlight will reach the bottom, and the green
plants on the bottom will disappear. As a consequence, the bottom sediments,
which contain phosphorus from dead algae, will be less stable, and phosphorous
will be released from the bottom. More discharge of phosphorus from outside
will trigger even more phosphorus from the bottom. This positive feedback will
eventually force the lake to flip or “bifurcate” from clear to turbid water. Recent
work by ecologists and environmental economists has investigated these dynam-
ics and shown that such flips can occur over as short a period as a month
(Scheffer, 1998; Carpenter, Ludwig and Brock, 1999; Brock and Starrett, 2003).
Another possible bifurcation arises in certain climate models that indicate that
a rise in greenhouse gases might reverse the direction of the Atlantic stream
that now warms northern Europe. Paleo-climatic history shows that such rever-
sals have been common.16
Nonlinearities in ecosystem dynamics imply the presence of serious downside
risks related to the losses of natural capital. Central estimates of the shadow prices
for natural capital are likely to be too low if one only considers central cases rather
than the entire distribution of potential outcomes from losses of natural capital.
Thus, the expected values of genuine investment or of changes in per capita
genuine wealth might well be lower than the values emerging when one employs
only central values for parameters. Accounting for risk-aversion could lower these
estimates even further.
While there may be uncertainty about whether various countries are meeting
the sustainability criterion, the need for vigorous public policies to support more
efficient consumption and investment choices is unambiguous. Through regula-
tion, taxes or the establishment of clearer or more secure property rights, public
policy can help prices of natural and environmental resources better approximate

16
Mastrandrea and Schneider (2001) have employed a climate-economy model to investigate the
possibility of reversals and to assess the implications for climate policy.
Kenneth Arrow et al. 169

their social cost. These policies can help prevent excessive resource depletion and
promote higher genuine investment. Such policies are justified on efficiency
grounds whether or not genuine investment currently is positive.17 Although the
implementation of public policies that satisfy a benefit-cost test does not in theory
guarantee sustainability, such policies do not necessarily conflict with sustainability,
either. Indeed, our sense is that policies of this sort— especially those that deal with
underpricing of natural resources or environmental amenities—will improve mat-
ters along the sustainability dimension. When one views desertification in China,
water contamination in Senegal and forest depletion in Haiti, it is hard to imagine
that the establishment of property rights or improved pricing of natural resources
could worsen the prospects of future generations.
Beyond policy action, further research is needed to identify the areas where
current consumption poses a threat to sustainability and to quantify the potential
losses. We need to develop better data quantifying the losses of natural capital and
the potential for substitution between various forms of capital.
Further, to complement the rather simple analytical calculations of changes in
genuine wealth, we need to make more use of disaggregated numerical growth
models. Such models can contain considerable detail in the interaction of various
forms of capital and the services they generate. Current estimates of genuine wealth
depend crucially on the values assigned to shadow prices, yet the empirical basis for
these prices is very weak. Numerical growth models can be used to project growth
paths of economies and the sensitivity of these paths to changes in capital stocks. In
this way, they can generate much better assessments of the critical shadow prices.
Additional information of this kind will help reduce uncertainties about changes in
genuine wealth and clarify the extent to which current consumption levels might
imperil the quality of life of future generations.

y We are grateful to Geir Asheim, Jack Pezzey and the editors of this journal for very helpful
suggestions, and to Oren Ahoobim and Justin Diener for excellent research assistance. We also
thank the William and Flora Hewlett Foundation for financial support and the Beijer
Institute for Ecological Economics, Stockholm, for sponsoring the workshops from which this
paper emerged.

17
The rationale for many public policies remains strong irrespective of whether genuine investment is
positive or negative. From this, one might conclude that quantifying genuine investment is not very
useful. But measuring genuine investment still has significant value. By providing an overall “scorecard”
as to whether a nation is investing enough to sustain the welfare of future generations, it can offer an
important summary assessment that can help mobilize the general public and politicians.
170 Journal of Economic Perspectives

References

Arrow, Kenneth J. 2000. “Observations on So- Cooper, Ben, Cecelia Garcia-Peñalosa and
cial Capital,” in Social Capital: A Multifaceted Per- Peter Funk. 2001. “Status Effects and Negative
spective. P. Dasgupta and I. Serageldin, eds. Utility Growth.” Economic Journal. 111:2,
Washington, D.C.: World Bank, pp. 3–5. pp. 642– 65.
Arrow, Kenneth J. and Mordecai Kurz. 1970. Daily, Gretchen C., ed. 1997. Nature’s Services:
Public Investment, the Rate of Return and Optimal Societal Dependence on Natural Ecosystems. Washing-
Fiscal Policy. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University ton, D.C.: Island Press.
Press. Daily, Gretchen C. et al. 2001. “The Value of
Arrow, Kenneth J., Partha Dasgupta and Karl- Nature and the Nature of Value.” Science. July 21,
Göran Mäler. 2003a. “The Genuine Savings Cri- 289, pp. 395–96.
terion and the Value of Population.” Economic Dasgupta, Partha. 1990. “The Environment as
Theory. 21:2, pp. 217–55. a Commodity.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy.
Arrow, Kenneth J., Partha Dasgupta and Karl- 6:2, pp. 51– 67.
Göran Mäler. 2003b. “Evaluating Projects and Dasgupta, Partha. 1993. An Inquiry into Well-
Assessing Sustainable Development in Imperfect Being and Destitution. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Economies” Environmental and Resource Econom- Dasgupta, Partha. 2001a. Human Well-Being
ics. 46:4, pp. 647– 85. and the Natural Environment. Oxford and New
Arrow, Kenneth J. et al. 1996. “Intertemporal York: Oxford University Press.
Equity, Discounting, and Economic Efficiency,” Dasgupta, Partha. 2001b. “On Population and
in Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Di- Resources: Reply.” Population and Development Re-
mensions of Climate Change. J. P. Bruce, H. Lee view. 27:4, pp. 748 –54.
and E. R. Haites, eds. Cambridge, UK, New York
Dasgupta, Partha and G. M. Heal. 1979. Eco-
and Melbourne: Cambridge University Press,
nomic Theory and Exhaustible Resources. Cam-
pp. 125– 44.
bridge: Cambridge University Press.
Asheim, Geir. 1994. “Net National Product as
Dasgupta, Partha and Karl-Göran Mäler. 2000.
an Indicator of Sustainability.” Scandinavian Jour-
“Net National Product, Wealth, and Social Well-
nal of Economics. 96:2, pp. 257– 65.
Being.” Environment and Development Economics.
Asheim, Geir. 2003. “Green National Ac-
5:2, pp. 69 –93.
counts for Welfare and Sustainability: A Taxon-
Duesenberry, James S. 1949. Income, Saving,
omy of Assumptions and Results.” Scottish Journal
and the Theory of Consumer Behavior. Cambridge,
of Political Economy. 50:2, pp. 113–30.
Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Barnett, Harold and Chandler Morse. 1963.
Ehrlich, Paul R. and Anne H. Ehrlich. 1990.
Scarcity and Growth. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins
University Press. The Population Explosion. New York: Simon and
Bohn, Henning and Robert T. Deacon. 2000. Schuster.
“Ownership Risk, Investment, and the Use of Frank, Robert. 1985a. Choosing the Right Pond:
Natural Resources.” American Economic Review. Human Behavior and the Quest for Status. New
9:3, pp. 526 – 49. York: Oxford University Press.
Brock, W. A. and D. Starrett. 2003. “Managing Frank, Robert. 1985b. “The Demand for Un-
Systems with Non-Convex Positive Feedbacks.” observable and Other Nonpositional Goods.”
Environmental and Resource Economics. 46:4, American Economic Review. 75:1, pp. 101–16.
pp. 575– 602. Hall, Robert. 1988. “Intertemporal Substitu-
Carpenter, Stephen R., D. Ludwig and W.A. tion in Consumption.” Journal of Political Econ-
Brock. 1999. “Management of Eutrophication omy. 96:2, pp. 339 –57.
for Lakes Subject to Potentially Irreversible Hamilton, Kirk. 2000. “Genuine Saving as a
Change.” Ecological Applications. 9:3, pp. 751– Sustainability Indicator.” Working paper, Envi-
71. ronment Department, World Bank, January.
Chichilnisky, Graciela. 1994. “North-South Hamilton, Kirk. 2002. “Savings Rules and Sus-
Trade and the Global Environment.” American tainability.” Working paper, Environment De-
Economic Review. 84:3, pp. 851–74. partment, World Bank.
Collins, Susan and Barry Bosworth. 1996. Hamilton, Kirk and Michael Clemens. 1999.
“Economic Growth in East Asia: Accumulation “Genuine Savings Rates in Developing Coun-
versus Assimilation.” Brookings Papers on Economic tries.” World Bank Economic Review. 13:2, pp. 333–
Activity. 2, pp. 135–203. 56.
Are We Consuming Too Much? 171

Heal, Geoffrey M. 1998. Valuing the Future: Mastrandrea, Michael and Stephen H. Schnei-
Economic Theory and Sustainability. New York: Co- der. 2001. “Integrated Assessment of Abrupt Cli-
lumbia University Press. matic Changes.” Climate Policy. 1:4, pp. 433– 49.
Heal, Geoffrey M. 2003. “Optimality or Sus- McNeill, John Robert. 2000. Something New Un-
tainability?” in Economics for an Imperfect World. der the Sun: An Environmental History of the Twen-
Richard Arnott, Bruce Greenwald, Ravi Kanbur tieth-Century World. New York: W.W. Norton.
and Barry Nalebuff, eds. Cambridge, Mass. and Myers, Norman and Jennifer Kent. 2000. Per-
London: MIT Press, pp. 331– 48. verse Subsidies: How Tax Dollars Can Undercut the
Heal, Geoffrey M. et al. 2001. “Protecting Environment and the Economy. Washington, D.C.:
Natural Capital: Ecosystem Service Districts.” Island Press.
Stanford Environmental Law Journal. 20:2, Ng, Yew-Kwang. 1987. “Relative Income Ef-
pp. 333– 64. fects and the Appropriate Level of Public Expen-
Howarth, Richard. 1996. “Status Effects and diture.” Oxford Economic Papers. 39:2, pp. 293–
Environmental Externalities.” Ecological Econom- 300.
ics. 16:1, pp. 25–34. Pearce, David and Giles Atkinson. 1995. “Mea-
Hussain, Athar, Nicholas Stern and Joseph suring Sustainable Development,” in Handbook of
Stiglitz. 2000. “Chinese Reforms from a Compar- Environmental Economics. D. W. Bromley, ed. Ox-
ative Perspective,” in Incentives, Organization, and ford: Basil Blackwell, pp. 166 – 81.
Public Economics. P. J. Hammond and G. D. Pearce, David, K. Hamilton and Giles Atkin-
Myles, eds. Oxford: Oxford University Press, son. 1996. “Measuring Sustainable Develop-
pp. 243–77. ment: Progress on Indicators.” Environment and
International Energy Agency. 1999. World En- Development Economics. 1, pp. 85–101.
ergy Outlook—1999 Insights. Looking at Energy Pezzey, John. 1992. “Sustainable Development
Subsidies: Getting the Price Right. London: IEA Concepts: An Economic Analysis.” World Bank
Publications. Environment Paper No. 2, World Bank, Wash-
Johnson, D. Gale. 2000. “Population, Food, ington, D.C.
and Knowledge.” American Economic Review. 90:1, Portney, Paul and John Weyant, eds. 1999.
pp. 1–14. Discounting and Intergenerational Equity. Washing-
Johnson, D. Gale. 2001. “On Population and ton, D.C.: Resources for the Future.
Resources: A Comment.” Population and Develop- Postel, Sandra L., Gretchen C. Daily and Paul
ment Review. 27:4, pp. 739 – 47. R. Ehrlich. 1996. “Human Appropriation of Re-
Klenow, Peter J. and Andres Rodrı́guez-Clare. newable Fresh Water.” Science. February 9, 271,
1997. “The Neoclassical Revival in Growth Eco- pp. 785– 88.
nomics: Has it Gone Too Far?” in NBER Macro- Ramsey, Frank P. 1928. “A Mathematical
economics Annual 1997. B. Bernanke and J. Theory of Saving.” Economic Journal. 38:4,
Rotemberg, eds. Cambridge, Mass. and London: pp. 543–59.
MIT Press, pp. 73–104. Scheffer, Marten. 1998. The Ecology of Shallow
Koopmans, Tjalling C. 1960. “Stationary Ordi- Lakes. London: Chapman and Hall.
nal Utility and Impatience.” Econometrica. 28:2, Schor, Juliet. 1998. The Overspent American.
pp. 287–309. New York: Basic Books.
Koopmans, Tjalling C. 1972. “Representation Sen, Amartya K. 1967. “Isolation, Assurance,
of Preference Orderings over Time,” in Decision and the Social Rate of Discount.” Quarterly Jour-
and Organization. C. B. McGuire and R. Radner, nal of Economics. 81:1, pp. 12–124.
eds. Amsterdam: North Holland, chapter 4. Solow, Robert M. 1974. “The Economics of
Levin, Simon, ed. 2001. Encyclopedia of Biodi- Resources or the Resources of Economics.”
versity. New York: Academic Press. American Economic Review. 64:2, pp. 1–14.
Lind, Robert C. 1964. “The Social Rate of Solow, Robert M. 1992. “An Almost Practical
Discount and the Optimal Rate of Investment: Step toward Sustainability.” Resources for the
Further Comment.” Quarterly Journal of Econom- Future 40th Anniversary Lecture, Washington,
ics. 78:2, pp. 336 – 45. D.C.: Resources for the Future.
Lind, Robert C., ed. 1982. Discounting for Time UNDP (United Nations Development Pro-
and Risk in Energy Policy. Baltimore: Johns Hop- gramme). 2003. Human Development Report. New
kins University Press. York: Oxford University Press.
Marglin, Stephen A. 1963. “The Social Rate of United States Office of Management and the
Discount and the Optimal Rate of Investment.” Budget. 1992. Circular A-94 Revised. Washington,
Quarterly Journal of Economics. 77:1, pp. 95–111. D.C.: United States Government Printing Office.
172 Journal of Economic Perspectives

Veblen, Thorstein. 1899. The Theory of the Lei- port 1992: Development and the Environment. Wash-
sure Class. New York: Penguin. ington, D.C.: World Bank.
Vitousek, P., P. R. Ehrlich, A. H. Ehrlich and World Bank. 1997. Expanding the Measure of
P. Matson. 1986. “Human Appropriation of Wealth: Indicators of Environmentally Sustainable De-
the Product of Photosynthesis.” BioScience. 36, velopment. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
pp. 368 –73. World Bank. 2003. World Development Indica-
Vitousek, P. M., H. A. Mooney, J. Lubchenco tors. Available at 具http://devdata.worldbank.
and J. M. Melillo. 1997. “Human Domination org/dataonline典, September.
of Earth’s Ecosystem.” Science. July 26, 277, World Commission on Environment and De-
pp. 494 –99. velopment. 1987. Our Common Future. New York:
World Bank. 1992. World Bank Development Re- Oxford University Press.
This article has been cited by:

1. Tesfa Worku, S. K. Tripathi, Deepak Khare. 2018. Household level tree planting and its implication
for environmental conservation in the Beressa Watershed of Ethiopia. Environmental Systems Research
6:1. . [CrossRef]
2. Karolina Safarzyńska, Jeroen C.J.M. van den Bergh. 2017. Financial stability at risk due to investing
rapidly in renewable energy. Energy Policy 108, 12-20. [CrossRef]
3. Marc Germain. 2017. Optimal Versus Sustainable Degrowth Policies. Ecological Economics 136,
266-281. [CrossRef]
4. Rintaro Yamaguchi, Shunsuke Managi. 2017. New Financing for Sustainable Development. The
Journal of Environment & Development 26:2, 214-239. [CrossRef]
5. Richard D. Horan, Eli P. Fenichel, David Finnoff, Carson Reeling. 2017. A Portfolio-Balancing
Approach to Natural Capital and Liabilities: Managing Livestock and Wildlife Diseases with Cross-
Species Transmission. Environmental and Resource Economics 314. . [CrossRef]
6. Isabel Almudi, Francisco Fatas-Villafranca, Jason Potts. 2017. Utopia competition: a new approach to
the micro-foundations of sustainability transitions. Journal of Bioeconomics 19:1, 165-185. [CrossRef]
7. Hideyuki Mizobuchi. 2017. Incorporating Sustainability Concerns in the Better Life Index:
Application of Corrected Convex Non-parametric Least Squares Method. Social Indicators Research
131:3, 947-971. [CrossRef]
8. Cinzia Colapinto, Danilo Liuzzi, Simone Marsiglio. 2017. Sustainability and intertemporal equity: a
multicriteria approach. Annals of Operations Research 251:1-2, 271-284. [CrossRef]
9. Nils Droste, Bartosz Bartkowski. 2017. Ecosystem Service Valuation for National Accounting: A Reply
to Obst, Hein and Edens (2016). Environmental and Resource Economics 48. . [CrossRef]
10. Martin Hensher, John Tisdell, Craig Zimitat. 2017. “Too much medicine”: Insights and explanations
from economic theory and research. Social Science & Medicine 176, 77-84. [CrossRef]
11. Martin Neve, Bertrand Hamaide. 2017. Environmental Kuznets Curve with Adjusted Net Savings
as a Trade-Off Between Environment and Development. Australian Economic Papers 56:1, 39-58.
[CrossRef]
12. Masayuki Sato, Sovannroeun Samreth, Kengo Sasaki. 2017. The impact of institutional factors on
the performance of genuine savings. International Journal of Sustainable Development & World Ecology
1-13. [CrossRef]
13. Afreen Siddiqi, Ross D Collins. 2017. Sociotechnical systems and sustainability: current and future
perspectives for inclusive development. Current Opinion in Environmental Sustainability 24, 7-13.
[CrossRef]
14. Joseph Ato Forson, Ponlapat Buracom, Guojin Chen, Theresa Yaaba Baah-Ennumh. 2017. Genuine
Wealth Per Capita as a Measure of Sustainability and the Negative Impact of Corruption on
Sustainable Growth in Sub-Sahara Africa. South African Journal of Economics . [CrossRef]
15. Pushpam Kumar. 2017. Innovative tools and new metrics for inclusive green economy. Current
Opinion in Environmental Sustainability 24, 47-51. [CrossRef]
16. Efthimia Pantzartzis, Francis T. Edum-Fotwe, Andrew D.F. Price. 2017. Sustainable healthcare
facilities: Reconciling bed capacity and local needs. International Journal of Sustainable Built
Environment . [CrossRef]
17. Nikolai Hoberg, Stefan Baumgärtner. 2017. Irreversibility and uncertainty cause an intergenerational
equity-efficiency trade-off. Ecological Economics 131, 75-86. [CrossRef]
18. Anthony FriendSystem of Accounts for Global Entropy-Production (SAGE-P): The Accounting in
the Topological Domain Space (TDS) of the Econosphere, Sociosphere, and the Ecosphere 99-137.
[CrossRef]
19. Robert Costanza, Gar Alperovitz, Herman Daly, Joshua Farley, Carol Franco, Tim Jackson, Ida
Kubiszewski, Juliet Schor, Peter VictorBuilding a Sustainable and Desirable Economy-in-Society-in-
Nature 367-454. [CrossRef]
20. Carsten Deckert. 2016. Ecological sustainability of material resources – Why material efficiency just
isn’t enough. uwf UmweltWirtschaftsForum 24:4, 325-335. [CrossRef]
21. Jing-Yu Liu, Shinichiro Fujimori, Toshihiko Masui. 2016. Temporal and spatial distribution of global
mitigation cost: INDCs and equity. Environmental Research Letters 11:11, 114004. [CrossRef]
22. Chuan-Zhong Li, Sebastian Villasante, Xueqin Zhu. 2016. Regime Shifts and Resilience in Fisheries
Management: A Case Study of the Argentinean Hake fishery. Environmental and Resource Economics
65:3, 623-637. [CrossRef]
23. Bibliography 497-531. [CrossRef]
24. Linna Li, Becky P. Y. Loo. 2016. Impact analysis of airport infrastructure within a sustainability
framework: Case studies on Hong Kong International Airport. International Journal of Sustainable
Transportation 10:9, 781-793. [CrossRef]
25. Joseph Ato Forson. 2016. A “recursive framework” of corruption and development. World Journal of
Entrepreneurship, Management and Sustainable Development 12:4, 282-298. [CrossRef]
26. Rintaro Yamaguchi, Masayuki Sato, Kazuhiro Ueta. 2016. Measuring Regional Wealth and Assessing
Sustainable Development: An Application to a Disaster-Torn Region in Japan. Social Indicators
Research 129:1, 365-389. [CrossRef]
27. John A. Cigliano, Amy Bauer, Megan M. Draheim, Melissa M. Foley, Carolyn J. Lundquist, Julie-
Beth McCarthy, Katheryn W. Patterson, Andrew J. Wright, E. C. M. Parsons. 2016. The Kraken
in the Aquarium: Questions that Urgently Need to be Addressed in Order to Advance Marine
Conservation. Frontiers in Marine Science 3. . [CrossRef]
28. Genevieve Alberts, Zeynep Gurguc, Pantelis Koutroumpis, Ralf Martin, Mirabelle Muûls, Tamaryn
Napp. 2016. Competition and norms: A self-defeating combination?. Energy Policy 96, 504-523.
[CrossRef]
29. Neil Simcock, Caroline Mullen. 2016. Energy demand for everyday mobility and domestic life:
Exploring the justice implications. Energy Research & Social Science 18, 1-6. [CrossRef]
30. Luca Panzone, Denis Hilton, Laura Sale, Doron Cohen. 2016. Socio-demographics, implicit attitudes,
explicit attitudes, and sustainable consumption in supermarket shopping. Journal of Economic
Psychology 55, 77-95. [CrossRef]
31. Xuemei Bai, Sander van der Leeuw, Karen O’Brien, Frans Berkhout, Frank Biermann, Eduardo
S. Brondizio, Christophe Cudennec, John Dearing, Anantha Duraiappah, Marion Glaser, Andrew
Revkin, Will Steffen, James Syvitski. 2016. Plausible and desirable futures in the Anthropocene: A
new research agenda. Global Environmental Change 39, 351-362. [CrossRef]
32. Vincenzo Patrizii, Anna Pettini, Giuliano Resce. 2016. The Cost of Well-Being. Social Indicators
Research . [CrossRef]
33. Sabine Fuss, Claudine Chen, Michael Jakob, Annika Marxen, Narasimha D. Rao, Ottmar Edenhofer.
2016. Could resource rents finance universal access to infrastructure? A first exploration of needs and
rents. Environment and Development Economics 1-22. [CrossRef]
34. Paul R. Ehrlich, Anne H. Ehrlich. 2016. Population, Resources, and the Faith-Based Economy: the
Situation in 2016. BioPhysical Economics and Resource Quality 1:1. . [CrossRef]
35. Sun Sheng Han, Sadasivam Karuppannan. 2016. Non-transport household energy consumption in
Adelaide and Melbourne. Local Environment 21:3, 290-309. [CrossRef]
36. Eli P. Fenichel, Joshua K. Abbott, Jude Bayham, Whitney Boone, Erin M. K. Haacker, Lisa Pfeiffer.
2016. Measuring the value of groundwater and other forms of natural capital. Proceedings of the
National Academy of Sciences 113:9, 2382-2387. [CrossRef]
37. Alain de Serres, Fabrice Murtin. 2016. Your Money or Your Life: Green Growth Policies and Welfare
in 2050. Environmental and Resource Economics 63:3, 571-590. [CrossRef]
38. Eli P. Fenichel, Simon A. Levin, Bonnie McCay, Kevin St. Martin, Joshua K. Abbott, Malin L.
Pinsky. 2016. Wealth reallocation and sustainability under climate change. Nature Climate Change
6:3, 237-244. [CrossRef]
39. Bassem Kamar, Damyana Bakardzhieva. 2016. Beyond the Optimistic Curse: A New Multiscenario
Approach to Debt Sustainability Assessment. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 52:1, 110-122.
[CrossRef]
40. Enrico Ivaldi, Guido Bonatti, Riccardo Soliani. 2016. The Construction of a Synthetic Index
Comparing Multidimensional Well-Being in the European Union. Social Indicators Research 125:2,
397-430. [CrossRef]
41. Elettra Agliardi, Mehmet Pinar, Thanasis Stengos. 2016. Air and water pollution over time
and industries with stochastic dominance. Stochastic Environmental Research and Risk Assessment .
[CrossRef]
42. Mark Buchanan. 2015. Non-optimal optimization. Nature Physics 11:12, 984-984. [CrossRef]
43. Stephen Polasky, Benjamin Bryant, Peter Hawthorne, Justin Johnson, Bonnie Keeler, Derric
Pennington. 2015. Inclusive Wealth as a Metric of Sustainable Development. Annual Review of
Environment and Resources 40:1, 445-466. [CrossRef]
44. Sarah Whitmee, Andy Haines, Chris Beyrer, Frederick Boltz, Anthony G Capon, Braulio Ferreira de
Souza Dias, Alex Ezeh, Howard Frumkin, Peng Gong, Peter Head, Richard Horton, Georgina M
Mace, Robert Marten, Samuel S Myers, Sania Nishtar, Steven A Osofsky, Subhrendu K Pattanayak,
Montira J Pongsiri, Cristina Romanelli, Agnes Soucat, Jeanette Vega, Derek Yach. 2015. Safeguarding
human health in the Anthropocene epoch: report of The Rockefeller Foundation–Lancet Commission
on planetary health. The Lancet 386:10007, 1973-2028. [CrossRef]
45. References 327-362. [CrossRef]
46. Stian B. Hackett, Erling Moxnes. 2015. Natural capital in integrated assessment models of climate
change. Ecological Economics 116, 354-361. [CrossRef]
47. Jerzy A Filar, Jacek B Krawczyk, Manju R Agrawal. 2015. Sustainability screw: role of relative
production and abatement time scales. Journal of the Operational Research Society 66:8, 1259-1269.
[CrossRef]
48. Marcelo Vinhal Nepomuceno, Michel Laroche. 2015. When Materialists Intend to Resist
Consumption: The Moderating Role of Self-Control and Long-Term Orientation. Journal of Business
Ethics . [CrossRef]
49. G. Lazzaro, G. Botter. 2015. Run-of-river power plants in Alpine regions: Whither optimal capacity?.
Water Resources Research 51:7, 5658-5676. [CrossRef]
50. Anne D. Guerry, Stephen Polasky, Jane Lubchenco, Rebecca Chaplin-Kramer, Gretchen C. Daily,
Robert Griffin, Mary Ruckelshaus, Ian J. Bateman, Anantha Duraiappah, Thomas Elmqvist, Marcus
W. Feldman, Carl Folke, Jon Hoekstra, Peter M. Kareiva, Bonnie L. Keeler, Shuzhuo Li, Emily
McKenzie, Zhiyun Ouyang, Belinda Reyers, Taylor H. Ricketts, Johan Rockström, Heather Tallis,
Bhaskar Vira. 2015. Natural capital and ecosystem services informing decisions: From promise to
practice. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 201503751. [CrossRef]
51. Humberto Llavador, John E. Roemer, Joaquim Silvestre. 2015. North–south convergence and the
allocation of CO2 emissions. Climatic Change 130:3, 383-395. [CrossRef]
52. Peter Bartelmus. 2015. How bad is climate change?. Environmental Development 14, 53-62. [CrossRef]
53. Erik Ansink, Hans-Peter Weikard. 2015. Composition properties in the river claims problem. Social
Choice and Welfare 44:4, 807-831. [CrossRef]
54. Adrian Boos. 2015. Genuine Savings as an Indicator for “Weak” Sustainability: Critical Survey and
Possible Ways forward in Practical Measuring. Sustainability 7:4, 4146-4182. [CrossRef]
55. Simone Franceschini, Mario Pansera. 2015. Beyond unsustainable eco-innovation: The role of
narratives in the evolution of the lighting sector. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 92, 69-83.
[CrossRef]
56. Simon Levin. 2015. What Mathematics can do for Sustainability. Bulletin of Mathematical Biology
77:2, 251-253. [CrossRef]
57. Elettra Agliardi, Mehmet Pinar, Thanasis Stengos. 2015. An environmental degradation index based
on stochastic dominance. Empirical Economics 48:1, 439-459. [CrossRef]
58. Eli P. Fenichel, Jinhua Zhao. 2015. Sustainability and Substitutability. Bulletin of Mathematical Biology
77:2, 348-367. [CrossRef]
59. Moritz C. Remig. 2015. Unraveling the veil of fuzziness: A thick description of sustainability
economics. Ecological Economics 109, 194-202. [CrossRef]
60. Géraldine Thiry. 2015. Beyond GDP: Conceptual Grounds of Quantification. The Case of the Index
of Economic Well-Being (IEWB). Social Indicators Research 121:2, 313. [CrossRef]
61. Carlos Cuerpo, Inês Drumond, Julia Lendvai, Peter Pontuch, Rafal Raciborski. 2015. Private sector
deleveraging in Europe. Economic Modelling 44, 372-383. [CrossRef]
62. Lee H. EndressScarcity, Security, and Sustainable Development 49-66. [CrossRef]
63. Majah-Leah V. Ravago, Arsenio M. Balisacan, Ujjayant ChakravortyThe Principles and Practice of
Sustainable Economic Development 3-10. [CrossRef]
64. Alessandro Tavoni, Simon Levin. 2014. Managing the climate commons at the nexus of ecology,
behaviour and economics. Nature Climate Change 4:12, 1057-1063. [CrossRef]
65. Koji Tokimatsu, Rintaro Yamguchi, Masayuki Sato, Rieko Yasuoka, Masahiro Nishio, Kazuhiro Ueta.
2014. Assessing future sustainability by forecast of Genuine Savings paths. Environmental Economics
and Policy Studies 16:4, 359-379. [CrossRef]
66. M. Jakob, O. Edenhofer. 2014. Green growth, degrowth, and the commons. Oxford Review of
Economic Policy 30:3, 447-468. [CrossRef]
67. Dusan P. Sekulic, Rahul Nehete, Cheng-Nien Yu, Hai Fu. 2014. An energy sustainability metric.
Energy 74, 37-44. [CrossRef]
68. Hideyuki Mizobuchi. 2014. Measuring World Better Life Frontier: A Composite Indicator for OECD
Better Life Index. Social Indicators Research 118:3, 987-1007. [CrossRef]
69. Bibliography 319-336. [CrossRef]
70. Timothy J. Richards, Gareth P. Green. 2014. Environmental Choices and Hyperbolic Discounting:
An Experimental Analysis. Environmental and Resource Economics . [CrossRef]
71. Charlene Xie, Yang Liu, Sheng-xiang SheA behavioral study on the value of elasticity of marginal
utility in environmental risks 187-192. [CrossRef]
72. Rintaro Yamaguchi. 2014. Inclusive wealth with a changing but aging population. Economics Letters
124:1, 21-25. [CrossRef]
73. Koji Tokimatsu, Rieko Yasuoka, Masahiro Nishio, Kazuhiro Ueta. 2014. A study on forecasting paths
of genuine savings and wealth without and with carbon dioxide constraints: development of shadow
price functions. Environment, Development and Sustainability 16:3, 723-745. [CrossRef]
74. Erling Moxnes. 2014. Discounting, climate and sustainability. Ecological Economics 102, 158-166.
[CrossRef]
75. John Dobra, Matt Dobra. 2014. Another look at non-renewable resource exhaustion. Mineral
Economics 27:1, 33-41. [CrossRef]
76. Hans-Jürgen Engelbrecht. 2014. A Comparison of Macro-Level Sustainability Indices for OECD
Countries: Conceptual and Measurement Issues. Economic Papers: A journal of applied economics and
policy 33:2, 137-152. [CrossRef]
77. Ted J. Lawrence, George R. Robinson. 2014. Reckoning perverse outcomes of resource conservation
policies using the Ecological Footprint. Ecological Indicators 41, 87-95. [CrossRef]
78. Noël Bonneuil, Raouf Boucekkine. 2014. Viable Ramsey economies. Canadian Journal of Economics/
Revue canadienne d'économique 47:2, 422-441. [CrossRef]
79. Bunafsha Mislimshoeva, Robert Hable, Manuchehr Fezakov, Cyrus Samimi, Abdulnazar
Abdulnazarov, Thomas Koellner. 2014. Factors Influencing Households' Firewood Consumption in
the Western Pamirs, Tajikistan. Mountain Research and Development 34:2, 147-156. [CrossRef]
80. Anantha Kumar Duraiappah, Stanley Tanyi Asah, Eduardo S Brondizio, Nicolas Kosoy, Patrick
J O’Farrell, Anne-Helene Prieur-Richard, Suneetha M Subramanian, Kazuhiko Takeuchi. 2014.
Managing the mismatches to provide ecosystem services for human well-being: a conceptual
framework for understanding the New Commons. Current Opinion in Environmental Sustainability
7, 94-100. [CrossRef]
81. Mehmet Pinar, Caterina Cruciani, Silvio Giove, Matteo Sostero. 2014. Constructing the FEEM
sustainability index: A Choquet integral application. Ecological Indicators 39, 189-202. [CrossRef]
82. James H. Brown, Joseph R. Burger, William R. Burnside, Michael Chang, Ana D. Davidson, Trevor
S. Fristoe, Marcus J. Hamilton, Sean T. Hammond, Astrid Kodric-Brown, Norman Mercado-Silva,
Jeffrey C. Nekola, Jordan G. Okie. 2014. Macroecology meets macroeconomics: Resource scarcity and
global sustainability. Ecological Engineering 65, 24-32. [CrossRef]
83. Quentin Grafton, Tom Kompas, Ngo Van Long. 2014. Increase in Risk and its Effects on Welfare and
Optimal Policies in a Dynamic Setting: The Case of Global Pollution. The Geneva Risk and Insurance
Review 39:1, 40-64. [CrossRef]
84. Partha Dasgupta. 2014. The UK-NEA Papers: Introduction. Environmental and Resource Economics
57:2, 169-174. [CrossRef]
85. Brian M. Donovan, David Moreno Mateos, Jonathan F. Osborne, Daniel J. Bisaccio. 2014. Revising
the Economic Imperative for US STEM Education. PLoS Biology 12:1, e1001760. [CrossRef]
86. M. Das Gupta. 2014. Population, Poverty, and Climate Change. The World Bank Research Observer
. [CrossRef]
87. A. Markandya, M. González-Eguino, P. Criqui, S. Mima. 2014. Low climate stabilisation under diverse
growth and convergence scenarios. Energy Policy 64, 288-301. [CrossRef]
88. Ian Ferguson. 2013. Assessing sustainability in certification schemes. Australian Forestry 76:3-4,
183-193. [CrossRef]
89. Sebastián Villasante, David Rodríguez-González, Manel Antelo, Susana Rivero-Rodríguez, José A. de
Santiago, Gonzalo Macho. 2013. All Fish for China?. AMBIO 42:8, 923-936. [CrossRef]
90. Dale Squires, Niels Vestergaard. 2013. Technical Change and The Commons. Review of Economics
and Statistics 95:5, 1769-1787. [CrossRef]
91. Koji Tokimatsu, Rieko Yasuoka, Masahiro Nishio, Kazuhiro Ueta. 2013. Sustainability and the
measurement of future paths in genuine savings: case studies. International Journal of Sustainable
Development & World Ecology 1-12. [CrossRef]
92. Lieske Voget-Kleschin. 2013. Employing the Capability Approach in Conceptualizing Sustainable
Development. Journal of Human Development and Capabilities 14:4, 483-502. [CrossRef]
93. Ingrid Woolard, Murray Leibbrandt, Jane FortsonSocial Programs and Transfers: Are We Learning?
361-389. [CrossRef]
94. Måns Nilsson, Paul Lucas, Tetsuro Yoshida. 2013. Towards an Integrated Framework for SDGs:
Ultimate and Enabling Goals for the Case of Energy. Sustainability 5:10, 4124-4151. [CrossRef]
95. Clive L. Spash. 2013. The shallow or the deep ecological economics movement?. Ecological Economics
93, 351-362. [CrossRef]
96. Tetsuzo Yasunari, Daniel Niles, Makoto Taniguchi, Deliang Chen. 2013. Asia: proving ground for
global sustainability. Current Opinion in Environmental Sustainability 5:3-4, 288-292. [CrossRef]
97. Koji Tokimatsu, Ryota Ii, Rintaro Yamaguchi, Masayuki Sato, Rieko Yasuoka, Masahiro Nishio,
Kazuhiro Ueta. 2013. Measuring future paths of alternative sustainability indicators: an assessment
of IPCC SRES scenarios. International Journal of Sustainable Development & World Ecology 20:4,
273-286. [CrossRef]
98. Jianguo Wu. 2013. Landscape sustainability science: ecosystem services and human well-being in
changing landscapes. Landscape Ecology 28:6, 999-1023. [CrossRef]
99. John Gowdy, J. Barkley Rosser, Loraine Roy. 2013. The evolution of hyperbolic discounting:
Implications for truly social valuation of the future. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 90,
S94-S104. [CrossRef]
100. Joseph Nicolette, Stephanie Burr, Mark Rockel. 2013. A Practical Approach for Demonstrating
Environmental Sustainability and Stewardship through a Net Ecosystem Service Analysis.
Sustainability 5:5, 2152-2177. [CrossRef]
101. L. M. Hunt, S. G. Sutton, R. Arlinghaus. 2013. Illustrating the critical role of human dimensions
research for understanding and managing recreational fisheries within a social-ecological system
framework. Fisheries Management and Ecology 20:2-3, 111-124. [CrossRef]
102. E. P. Fenichel, B. Gentner, R. Arlinghaus. 2013. Normative considerations for recreational fishery
management: a bioeconomic framework for linking positive science and normative fisheries policy
decisions. Fisheries Management and Ecology 20:2-3, 223-233. [CrossRef]
103. Raouf Boucekkine, Giorgio Fabbri. 2013. Assessing Parfit’s Repugnant Conclusion within a canonical
endogenous growth set-up. Journal of Population Economics 26:2, 751-767. [CrossRef]
104. S. J. Cooke, L. Sack, C. E. Franklin, A. P. Farrell, J. Beardall, M. Wikelski, S. L. Chown. 2013.
What is conservation physiology? Perspectives on an increasingly integrated and essential science.
Conservation Physiology 1:1, cot001-cot001. [CrossRef]
105. S. Suweis, A. Rinaldo, A. Maritan, P. D'Odorico. 2013. Water-controlled wealth of nations. Proceedings
of the National Academy of Sciences 110:11, 4230-4233. [CrossRef]
106. Sarah Parks, John Gowdy. 2013. What have economists learned about valuing nature? A review essay.
Ecosystem Services 3, e1-e10. [CrossRef]
107. Ola Flaaten. 2013. Institutional quality and catch performance of fishing nations. Marine Policy 38,
267-276. [CrossRef]
108. Tong Wu, Yeon-Su Kim. 2013. Pricing ecosystem resilience in frequent-fire ponderosa pine forests.
Forest Policy and Economics 27, 8-12. [CrossRef]
109. Åsa Jansson. 2013. Reaching for a sustainable, resilient urban future using the lens of ecosystem
services. Ecological Economics 86, 285-291. [CrossRef]
110. Magnus Lindmark, Sevil Acar. 2013. Sustainability in the making? A historical estimate of Swedish
sustainable and unsustainable development 1850–2000. Ecological Economics 86, 176-187. [CrossRef]
111. P. R. Ehrlich, A. H. Ehrlich. 2013. Can a collapse of global civilization be avoided?. Proceedings of the
Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 280:1754, 20122845-20122845. [CrossRef]
112. Jeannine Cavender-Bares, James Heffernan, Elizabeth King, Stephen Polasky, Patricia Balvanera,
William C. ClarkSustainability and Biodiversity 71-84. [CrossRef]
113. Koji Tokimatsu, Rintaro Yamaguchi, Masayuki Sato, Rieko Yasuoka, Masahiro Nishio, Kazuhiro
Ueta. 2012. Measuring sustainable development for the future with climate change mitigation; a
case study of applying an integrated assessment model under IPCC SRES scenarios. Environment,
Development and Sustainability 14:6, 915-938. [CrossRef]
114. Eric Neumayer. 2012. Human Development and Sustainability. Journal of Human Development and
Capabilities 13:4, 561-579. [CrossRef]
115. Susanna Khavul, Garry D. Bruton. 2012. Harnessing Innovation for Change: Sustainability and
Poverty in Developing Countries. Journal of Management Studies no-no. [CrossRef]
116. Sadasivam Karuppannan, S. P. Sekar. 2012. A bottom-up approach towards the assessment of
ecological footprints and biocapacity. Local Environment 17:8, 897-913. [CrossRef]
117. Paul R. Ehrlich, Anne H. Ehrlich. 2012. Solving the human predicament. International Journal of
Environmental Studies 69:4, 557-565. [CrossRef]
118. Stamatios Christopoulos, Balazs Horvath, Michael Kull. 2012. ADVANCING THE
GOVERNANCE OF CROSS-SECTORAL POLICIES FOR SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT:
A METAGOVERNANCE PERSPECTIVE. Public Administration and Development 32:3, 305-323.
[CrossRef]
119. Adrian Boos, Karin Holm-Müller. 2012. A theoretical overview of the relationship between the
resource curse and genuine savings as an indicator for “weak” sustainability. Natural Resources Forum
36:3, 145-159. [CrossRef]
120. John P. Moriarty. 2012. Theorising scenario analysis to improve future perspective planning in
tourism. Journal of Sustainable Tourism 20:6, 779-800. [CrossRef]
121. Prakash Kotecha, Urmila Diwekar, Heriberto Cabezas. 2012. Model-based approach to study the
impact of biofuels on the sustainability of an ecological system. Clean Technologies and Environmental
Policy . [CrossRef]
122. Kenneth J. Arrow, Partha Dasgupta, Lawrence H. Goulder, Kevin J. Mumford, Kirsten Oleson.
2012. Sustainability and the measurement of wealth. Environment and Development Economics 17:03,
317-353. [CrossRef]
123. Samuel Alexander. 2012. Planned economic contraction: the emerging case for degrowth.
Environmental Politics 21:3, 349-368. [CrossRef]
124. D. Helm, C. Hepburn. 2012. The economic analysis of biodiversity: an assessment. Oxford Review
of Economic Policy 28:1, 1-21. [CrossRef]
125. Meera Tiwari, Solava Ibrahim. 2012. Sustainable Human Development at the Grass Roots: Different
Contexts, Similar Ingredients?. Oxford Development Studies 40:1, 69-85. [CrossRef]
126. Hélène Cherrier, Mathilde Szuba, Nil Özçağlar-Toulouse. 2012. Barriers to downward carbon
emission: Exploring sustainable consumption in the face of the glass floor. Journal of Marketing
Management 28:3-4, 397-419. [CrossRef]
127. Stéphane Hallegatte. 2012. A framework to investigate the economic growth impact of sea level rise.
Environmental Research Letters 7:1, 015604. [CrossRef]
128. Anthony FriendSystem of Accounts for Global Entropy-Production (SAGE-P): The Accounting in
the Topological Domain Space (TDS) of the Econosphere, Sociosphere, and the Ecosphere 25-51.
[CrossRef]
129. Maurício Fuks. 2012. Reflexões sobre o paradigma da economia ecológica para a gestão ambiental.
Estudos Avançados 26:74, 105-120. [CrossRef]
130. S. Proost, K. Van Dender. 2011. What Long-Term Road Transport Future? Trends and Policy
Options. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 5:1, 44-65. [CrossRef]
131. Kieran P. Donaghy. 2011. Urban environmental imprints after globalization. Regional Environmental
Change . [CrossRef]
132. Prakash R. Kotecha, Urmila M. Diwekar, Heriberto CabezasExploring the Sustainability of Industrial
Production and Energy Generation with a Model System 3121-3128. [CrossRef]
133. Leonie J. Pearson, Yoshihisa Kashima, Craig J. Pearson. 2011. Clarifying protected and utilitarian
values of critical capital. Ecological Economics . [CrossRef]
134. Claudia M. Agudelo-Vera, Adriaan R. Mels, Karel J. Keesman, Huub H.M. Rijnaarts. 2011. Resource
management as a key factor for sustainable urban planning. Journal of Environmental Management
92:10, 2295-2303. [CrossRef]
135. F. Stuart Chapin, Mary E. Power, Steward T. A. Pickett, Amy Freitag, Julie A. Reynolds, Robert
B. Jackson, David M. Lodge, Clifford Duke, Scott L. Collins, Alison G. Power, Ann Bartuska.
2011. Earth Stewardship: science for action to sustain the human-earth system. Ecosphere 2:8, art89.
[CrossRef]
136. John P. Moriarty. 2011. A theory of benchmarking. Benchmarking: An International Journal 18:4,
588-611. [CrossRef]
137. Sebastián Villasante, David Rodríguez, Manel Antelo, Martin Quaas, Henrik Österblom. 2011. The
Global Seafood Market Performance Index: A theoretical proposal and potential empirical applications.
Marine Policy . [CrossRef]
138. Paul R. Ehrlich. 2011. A personal view: environmental education—its content and delivery. Journal
of Environmental Studies and Sciences . [CrossRef]
139. Helen Scarborough. 2011. Intergenerational equity and the social discount rate. Australian Journal of
Agricultural and Resource Economics 55:2, 145-158. [CrossRef]
140. Susana Ferreira, Mirko Moro. 2011. Constructing genuine savings indicators for Ireland, 1995–2005.
Journal of Environmental Management 92:3, 542-553. [CrossRef]
141. Simone Marsiglio. 2011. On the relationship between population change and sustainable development.
Research in Economics . [CrossRef]
142. Raouf Boucekkine, Natali Hritonenko, Yuri Yatsenko. 2011. Scarcity, regulation and endogenous
technical progress. Journal of Mathematical Economics . [CrossRef]
143. Jagdish N. Sheth, Nirmal K. Sethia, Shanthi Srinivas. 2011. Mindful consumption: a customer-centric
approach to sustainability. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science 39:1, 21-39. [CrossRef]
144. Giulia Wegner, Unai Pascual. 2011. Cost-benefit analysis in the context of ecosystem services for
human well-being: A multidisciplinary critique. Global Environmental Change . [CrossRef]
145. Hans-Jurgen Engelbrecht. 2011. Some empirics of the bivariate relationship between average
subjective well-being and the sustainable wealth of nations. Applied Economics 1-18. [CrossRef]
146. Timothée Ollivier, Pierre-Noël Giraud. 2011. Assessing sustainability, a comprehensive wealth
accounting prospect: An application to Mozambique. Ecological Economics 70:3, 503-512. [CrossRef]
147. Erik Ansink, Hans-Peter Weikard. 2011. Sequential sharing rules for river sharing problems. Social
Choice and Welfare . [CrossRef]
148. Justin Kozak, Christopher Lant, Sabina Shaikh, Guangxing Wang. 2011. The geography of ecosystem
service value: The case of the Des Plaines and Cache River wetlands, Illinois. Applied Geography 31:1,
303-311. [CrossRef]
149. Elettra Agliardi. 2011. Sustainability in Uncertain Economies. Environmental and Resource Economics
48:1, 71-82. [CrossRef]
150. James H. Brown, William R. Burnside, Ana D. Davidson, John P. DeLong, William C. Dunn, Marcus
J. Hamilton, Norman Mercado-Silva, Jeffrey C. Nekola, Jordan G. Okie, William H. Woodruff,
Wenyun Zuo. 2011. Energetic Limits to Economic Growth. BioScience 61:1, 19-26. [CrossRef]
151. Jason Potts, John Foster, Anna Straton. 2010. An entrepreneurial model of economic and
environmental co-evolution. Ecological Economics 70:2, 375-383. [CrossRef]
152. RASHID HASSAN. 2010. The double challenge of adapting to climate change while accelerating
development in sub-Saharan Africa. Environment and Development Economics 15:06, 661-685.
[CrossRef]
153. JOHN GOWDY, CHARLES HALL, KENT KLITGAARD, LISI KRALL. 2010. What Every
Conservation Biologist Should Know about Economic Theory. Conservation Biology 24:6, 1440-1447.
[CrossRef]
154. NATALI HRITONENKO, YURI YATSENKO. 2010. Age-Structured PDEs in Economics,
Ecology, and Demography: Optimal Control and Sustainability. Mathematical Population Studies 17:4,
191-214. [CrossRef]
155. David Pimentel, Michele Whitecraft, Zachary R. Scott, Leixin Zhao, Patricia Satkiewicz, Timothy J.
Scott, Jennifer Phillips, Daniel Szimak, Gurpreet Singh, Daniela O. Gonzalez, Tun Lin Moe. 2010.
Will Limited Land, Water, and Energy Control Human Population Numbers in the Future?. Human
Ecology 38:5, 599-611. [CrossRef]
156. S. M. Hsiang. 2010. Temperatures and cyclones strongly associated with economic production in the
Caribbean and Central America. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 107:35, 15367-15372.
[CrossRef]
157. Nathan Pelletier. 2010. Environmental sustainability as the first principle of distributive justice:
Towards an ecological communitarian normative foundation for ecological economics. Ecological
Economics 69:10, 1887-1894. [CrossRef]
158. Paul Ehrlich, Anne Ehrlich. 2010. The culture gap and its needed closures. International Journal of
Environmental Studies 67:4, 481-492. [CrossRef]
159. A. Bowen, N. Stern. 2010. Environmental policy and the economic downturn. Oxford Review of
Economic Policy 26:2, 137-163. [CrossRef]
160. C. Hepburn. 2010. Environmental policy, government, and the market. Oxford Review of Economic
Policy 26:2, 117-136. [CrossRef]
161. Partha Dasgupta. 2010. 20th Anniversary of EAERE: The European Association of Environmental
and Resource Economists. Environmental and Resource Economics 46:2, 135-137. [CrossRef]
162. Y. Hossein Farzin. 2010. Sustainability, Optimality, and Development Policy. Review of Development
Economics 14:2, 262-281. [CrossRef]
163. M. D. Smith, C. A. Roheim, L. B. Crowder, B. S. Halpern, M. Turnipseed, J. L. Anderson, F. Asche,
L. Bourillon, A. G. Guttormsen, A. Khan, L. A. Liguori, A. McNevin, M. I. O'Connor, D. Squires,
P. Tyedmers, C. Brownstein, K. Carden, D. H. Klinger, R. Sagarin, K. A. Selkoe. 2010. Sustainability
and Global Seafood. Science 327:5967, 784-786. [CrossRef]
164. Brian Walker, Leonie Pearson, Michael Harris, Karl-Göran Maler, Chuan-Zhong Li, Reinette Biggs,
Tim Baynes. 2010. Incorporating Resilience in the Assessment of Inclusive Wealth: An Example from
South East Australia. Environmental and Resource Economics 45:2, 183-202. [CrossRef]
165. P. Dasgupta. 2010. Nature's role in sustaining economic development. Philosophical Transactions of the
Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 365:1537, 5-11. [CrossRef]
166. Kenneth J. Arrow, Partha Dasgupta, Lawrence H. Goulder, Kevin Mumford, Kirsten OlesonChina,
the US, and Sustainability: Perspectives Based on Comprehensive Wealth 92-144. [CrossRef]
167. Jean-Paul Fitoussi, Éloi Laurent, Jacques Le CacheuxThe EU Environmental Strategy 160-186.
[CrossRef]
168. Chuku Agbai Chuku. 2010. Pursuing an integrated development and climate policy framework in
Africa: options for mainstreaming. Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies for Global Change 15:1, 41-52.
[CrossRef]
169. Partha DasguptaThe Place of Nature in Economic Development* 4977-5046. [CrossRef]
170. Prakash R. Kotecha, Urmila D. Diwekar, Joshua Templeton, Heriberto Cabezas. 2010. A Novel
Integrated Ecological Model for the study of Sustainability. IFAC Proceedings Volumes 43:5, 236-241.
[CrossRef]
171. Paul R. Ehrlich. 2009. Ecoethics: Now Central to All Ethics. Journal of Bioethical Inquiry 6:4, 417-436.
[CrossRef]
172. Ashish Goel, Adam Meyerson, Thomas A. Weber. 2009. Fair welfare maximization. Economic Theory
41:3, 465-494. [CrossRef]
173. R J Scholes. 2009. Syndromes of dryland degradation in southern Africa. African Journal of Range &
Forage Science 26:3, 113-125. [CrossRef]
174. Gordon H. Orians, David Policansky. 2009. Scientific Bases of Macroenvironmental Indicators. Annual
Review of Environment and Resources 34:1, 375-404. [CrossRef]
175. Juan Camilo Cárdenas. 2009. Experiments in Environment and Development. Annual Review of
Resource Economics 1:1, 157-182. [CrossRef]
176. Stephen Polasky, Kathleen Segerson. 2009. Integrating Ecology and Economics in the Study of
Ecosystem Services: Some Lessons Learned. Annual Review of Resource Economics 1:1, 409-434.
[CrossRef]
177. Felix S. Creutzig, Daniel M. Kammen. 2009. The Post-Copenhagen Roadmap Towards
Sustainability: Differentiated Geographic Approaches, Integrated Over Goals. Innovations: Technology,
Governance, Globalization 4:4, 301-321. [CrossRef]
178. Paul R. Ehrlich. 2009. Cultural evolution and the human predicament. Trends in Ecology & Evolution
24:8, 409-412. [CrossRef]
179. T. S. Aidt. 2009. Corruption, institutions, and economic development. Oxford Review of Economic
Policy 25:2, 271-291. [CrossRef]
180. Timothy G. Gutowski, Dusan P. Sekulic, Bhavik R. BakshiPreliminary thoughts on the application
of thermodynamics to the development of sustainability criteria 1-6. [CrossRef]
181. 2009. The Fate of Nauru and the Global Financial Meltdown. Conservation Biology 23:2, 257-258.
[CrossRef]
182. Jeroen C.J.M. van den Bergh. 2009. The GDP paradox. Journal of Economic Psychology 30:2, 117-135.
[CrossRef]
183. Stefan Baumgärtner, Frank Jöst, Ralph Winkler. 2009. Optimal dynamic scale and structure of a
multi-pollution economy. Ecological Economics 68:4, 1226-1238. [CrossRef]
184. Gretchen C Daily, Stephen Polasky, Joshua Goldstein, Peter M Kareiva, Harold A Mooney, Liba
Pejchar, Taylor H Ricketts, James Salzman, Robert Shallenberger. 2009. Ecosystem services in
decision making: time to deliver. Frontiers in Ecology and the Environment 7:1, 21-28. [CrossRef]
185. Partha Dasgupta. 2009. The Welfare Economic Theory of Green National Accounts. Environmental
and Resource Economics 42:1, 3-38. [CrossRef]
186. Simone Borghesi, Alessandro Vercelli. 2009. Greenhouse gas emissions and the energy system: Are
current trends sustainable?. International Journal of Global Energy Issues 32:1/2, 160. [CrossRef]
187. Robert J. AntonioClimate Change, the Resource Crunch, and The Global Growth Imperative 3-73.
[CrossRef]
188. William Rees. 2008. Human nature, eco-footprints and environmental injustice. Local Environment
13:8, 685-701. [CrossRef]
189. Guido Buenstorf, Christian Cordes. 2008. Can sustainable consumption be learned? A model of
cultural evolution. Ecological Economics 67:4, 646-657. [CrossRef]
190. H SCARBOROUGH, J BENNETT. 2008. Estimating intergenerational distribution preferences.
Ecological Economics 66:4, 575-583. [CrossRef]
191. K.-G. Maler, S. Aniyar, A. Jansson. 2008. Accounting for ecosystem services as a way to understand
the requirements for sustainable development. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 105:28,
9501-9506. [CrossRef]
192. Hans Kjellberg. 2008. Market practices and over-consumption. Consumption Markets & Culture 11:2,
151-167. [CrossRef]
193. Charles C. Mueller. 2008. Sustainable development: conceptualizations and measurement. Revista de
Economia Política 28:2, 207-225. [CrossRef]
194. Nicholas Stern. 2008. The Economics of Climate Change. American Economic Review 98:2, 1-37.
[Citation] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
195. NATALI HRITONENKO, YURI YATSENKO. 2008. Can Technological Change Sustain
Retirement in an Aging Population?. Mathematical Population Studies 15:2, 96-113. [CrossRef]
196. Colin D. Butler. 2008. Environmental Change, Injustice and Sustainability. Journal of Bioethical
Inquiry 5:1, 11-19. [CrossRef]
197. Yacov Tsur, Amos Zemel. 2008. Regulating environmental threats. Environmental and Resource
Economics 39:3, 297-310. [CrossRef]
198. Terrence S. Veeman. 2008. Development, Productivity, and Sustaining Natural Capital. Canadian
Journal of Agricultural Economics/Revue canadienne d'agroeconomie 56:1, 13-25. [CrossRef]
199. Paul R. Ehrlich. 2008. Demography and Policy: A View from Outside the Discipline. Population and
Development Review 34:1, 103-113. [CrossRef]
200. U. T. Srinivasan, S. P. Carey, E. Hallstein, P. A. T. Higgins, A. C. Kerr, L. E. Koteen, A. B. Smith, R.
Watson, J. Harte, R. B. Norgaard. 2008. The debt of nations and the distribution of ecological impacts
from human activities. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 105:5, 1768-1773. [CrossRef]
201. PAUL R. EHRLICH. 2008. Key issues for attention from ecological economists. Environment and
Development Economics 13:01. . [CrossRef]
202. Partha Dasgupta. 2008. Nature in Economics. Environmental and Resource Economics 39:1, 1-7.
[CrossRef]
203. P. R. SHUKLA, SUBASH DHAR, DIPTIRANJAN MAHAPATRA. 2008. Low-carbon society
scenarios for India. Climate Policy 8:sup1, S156-S176. [CrossRef]
204. Karl-Göran Mäler. 2008. Sustainable Development and Resilience in Ecosystems. Environmental and
Resource Economics 39:1, 17-24. [CrossRef]
205. Paul R. Ehrlich, Anne H. Ehrlich. 2008. Nature’s Economy and the Human Economy. Environmental
and Resource Economics 39:1, 9-16. [CrossRef]
206. James RoumassetPopulation and Agricultural Growth 1-13. [CrossRef]
207. Ioannis A. Kaskarelis. 2007. Economic science: what it is and what the scientists do not tell us.
International Journal of Social Economics 34:12, 914-922. [CrossRef]
208. Kevin Maréchal. 2007. The economics of climate change and the change of climate in economics.
Energy Policy 35:10, 5181-5194. [CrossRef]
209. PAUL R. EHRLICH, LAWRENCE H. GOULDER. 2007. Is Current Consumption Excessive? A
General Framework and Some Indications for the United States. Conservation Biology 21:5, 1145-1154.
[CrossRef]
210. KENNETH J. ARROW, GRETCHEN DAILY, PARTHA DASGUPTA, PAUL EHRLICH,
LAWRENCE GOULDER, GEOFFREY HEAL, SIMON LEVIN, KARL-GÖRAN MÄLER,
STEPHEN SCHNEIDER, DAVID STARRETT, BRIAN WALKER. 2007. Consumption,
Investment, and Future Well-Being: Reply to Daly et al. Conservation Biology 21:5, 1363-1365.
[CrossRef]
211. HERMAN E. DALY, BRIAN CZECH, DAVID L. TRAUGER, WILLIAM E. REES, MANSI
GROVER, TRACY DOBSON, STEPHEN C. TROMBULAK. 2007. Are We Consuming Too
Much?for What?. Conservation Biology 21:5, 1359-1362. [CrossRef]
212. B NORTON, D NOONAN. 2007. Ecology and valuation: Big changes needed. Ecological Economics
63:4, 664-675. [CrossRef]
213. J GOWDY. 2007. Toward an experimental foundation for benefit-cost analysis☆. Ecological Economics
63:4, 649-655. [CrossRef]
214. Sara J. Solnick, Li Hong, David Hemenway. 2007. Positional goods in the United States and China.
The Journal of Socio-Economics 36:4, 537-545. [CrossRef]
215. Brian Chi-ang Lin. 2007. A NEW VISION OF THE KNOWLEDGE ECONOMY. Journal of
Economic Surveys 21:3, 553-584. [CrossRef]
216. PARTHA DASGUPTA. 2007. Nature and the economy*. Journal of Applied Ecology 44:3, 475-487.
[CrossRef]
217. Louis Lefeber, Thomas Vietorisz. 2007. The Meaning of Social Efficiency. Review of Political Economy
19:2, 139-164. [CrossRef]
218. Partha Dasgupta. 2007. The idea of sustainable development. Sustainability Science 2:1, 5-11.
[CrossRef]
219. J MATERO, O SAASTAMOINEN. 2007. In search of marginal environmental valuations —
ecosystem services in Finnish forest accounting. Ecological Economics 61:1, 101-114. [CrossRef]
220. E. Wayne NafzigerFrom Seers to Sen: The Meaning of Economic Development 50-62. [CrossRef]
221. Oksana Mont, Raimund Bleischwitz. 2007. Sustainable consumption and resource management in the
light of life cycle thinking. European Environment 17:1, 59-76. [CrossRef]
222. Kai M.A. Chan, Terre SatterfieldJustice, Equity, and Biodiversity 1-9. [CrossRef]
223. Richard L. Revesz, Robert N. StavinsChapter 8 Environmental Law 499-589. [CrossRef]
224. Jason K. Levy, E.T. Moncur, Kaoru Takara. 2006. INTRODUCTION: ENHANCING THE
CAPACITY FOR SUSTAINABLE WATERSHED MANAGEMENT. Journal of the American
Water Resources Association 42:6, 1437-1439. [CrossRef]
225. Brian Chi-ang Lin. 2006. A sustainable perspective on the knowledge economy: A critique of Austrian
and mainstream views. Ecological Economics 60:1, 324-332. [CrossRef]
226. F. S. Chapin, A. L. Lovecraft, E. S. Zavaleta, J. Nelson, M. D. Robards, G. P. Kofinas, S. F. Trainor,
G. D. Peterson, H. P. Huntington, R. L. Naylor. 2006. Inaugural Article: Policy strategies to address
sustainability of Alaskan boreal forests in response to a directionally changing climate. Proceedings of
the National Academy of Sciences 103:45, 16637-16643. [CrossRef]
227. Yelena Kalyuzhnova, Michael Kaser. 2006. Prudential Management of Hydrocarbon Revenues in
Resource-rich Transition Economies. Post-Communist Economies 18:2, 167-187. [CrossRef]
228. John M. Gowdy. 2006. Evolutionary Theory and Economic Policy with Reference to Sustainability.
Journal of Bioeconomics 8:1, 1-19. [CrossRef]
229. C. Wyplosz. 2006. European Monetary Union: the dark sides of a major success. Economic Policy
21:46, 208-261. [CrossRef]
230. Stephen J. DeCanio, Paul Niemann. 2006. Equity effects of alternative assignments of global
environmental rights. Ecological Economics 56:4, 546-559. [CrossRef]
231. Stephen J. DeCanio. 2005. Descriptive or Conceptual Models? Contributions of Economics to the
Climate Policy Debate. International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics 5:4,
415-427. [CrossRef]
232. Juliet B. Schor. 2005. Prices and quantities: Unsustainable consumption and the global economy☆.
Ecological Economics 55:3, 309-320. [CrossRef]
233. Sara J. Solnick, David Hemenway. 2005. Are Positional Concerns Stronger in Some Domains than in
Others?. American Economic Review 95:2, 147-151. [Citation] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
234. Jon Christensen. 2005. Are We Consuming Too Much?. It turns out we may be worrying too much
about how much we consume and far too little about how to invest. Conservation in Practice 6:2,
64-70. [CrossRef]
235. Juliet B. Schor. 2005. Sustainable Consumption and Worktime Reduction. Journal of Industrial Ecology
9:1-2, 37-50. [CrossRef]

You might also like