You are on page 1of 8

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/235790824

Are the FDI inflow spillover effects on Malaysia's economic growth input
driven?

Article  in  Economic Modelling · June 2012


DOI: 10.1016/j.econmod.2012.04.010

CITATIONS READS

49 515

1 author:

Elsadig Ahmed
Multimedia University
158 PUBLICATIONS   449 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Bioeconomy And Its Connection To Knowledge-based Economy View project

Economically potential inbound markets for Malaysian tourism industry View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Elsadig Ahmed on 18 January 2018.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Economic Modelling 29 (2012) 1498–1504

Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect

Economic Modelling
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ecmod

Are the FDI inflow spillover effects on Malaysia's economic growth input driven?
Elsadig Musa Ahmed
Faculty of Business and Law, Multimedia University, 75450 Melaka, Malaysia

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: This paper inspects the influence of human capital, labour force, and absorptive capacity, physical capital as a
Accepted 7 April 2012 control variable, foreign direct investment (FDI) inflows and gross domestic product (GDP) on Malaysia's
productivity growth. A time series quarterly data from the period of 1999 to 2008 was used. The effects of
Keywords: FDI inflows on human capital, labour force, absorptive capacity and physical capital were investigated. The
FDI inflows
Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regression was applied to estimate the data in the first step and in the second
Economic growth
Input driven
step productivity indicators were calculated. The results show that the FDI inflows and inputs used are
Human capital negatively contributed to total factor productivity (TFP). Meanwhile, FDI plays a significant role in achieving
Absorptive capacity economic growth through input driven as indicated by the contribution of the TFP. In this regard, a significant
Malaysia positive relationship between human capital, labour force and absorptive capacity which determines the
spillover effect on Malaysian economic growth (GDP) was found and the physical capital has shown negative
relationship.
© 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction determining the knowledge based economy (K-economy) existence,


which is driven by human and technology knowledge, requiring a
The Organisation for Economic Cooperation (OECD), 2002 stated high skilled and creative human capital to facilitate the K-economy
that the total benefits of FDI for developing economies are well docu- activities. In this respect, human capital theory views education and
mented. Given the appropriate host-country policies and a basic level training as an investment that can yield social and private returns
of development, a preponderance of studies show that FDI triggers through augmented knowledge and skills for economic development
technology spillovers, assists human capital formation, contributes and social progress as stated by Schultz (1963). Furthermore, the
to international trade integration, helps create a more competitive economic argument in favour of knowledge-based education and
business environment and enhances enterprise development. All of training is linked to the perceived need of the global emerging K-
these contribute to higher economic growth, which is the most potent economy. That is based on the assumption that economic growth
tool for alleviating poverty in developing countries. Moreover, beyond and development currently are knowledge driven and human capital
the strictly economic benefits, FDI may help improve environmental is considered to be the centre of this development besides digital
and social conditions in the host country by, for example, transferring technology in the form of information and communication technolo-
“cleaner” technologies and leading to more socially responsible corpo- gy (ICT). But, the fact is that people will make the change, this ICT
rate policies. could be used as a means to facilitate economic activities which
Additionally, the FDI inflows helps as a compound for speedy eco- require human knowledge. Thus, the role of human capital is very
nomic growth experienced by East Asian countries by allowing these crucial in developing the innovation activities to turn them into
developing countries to jump into the development stages and to cutting products (knowledge products) and in this regard, the
catch up with the western developed countries, it constitutes also K-economy is called innovation economy. Dahlman and Nelson
an important advocate for improved social norms. In this respect, (1995) define national absorptive capacity as “the ability to learn
FDI plays a major role in the larger development agenda of the host and implement the technologies and associated practices of already
countries (Xiaolun, 2002). According to the author since the Golden developed countries”. National absorptive capacity is more than the
Age investment boom after World War II toward the East Asian eco- sum of the absorptive capabilities of domestic firms and includes
nomic miracles in the 1980s, there is ample evidence to demonstrate also the ability of human capital to develop new skills in general
that investment is a key ingredient to sustained economic growth. and managerial skills in particular which could aid to develop the do-
Moreover, according to Ramlee and Abu (2004), the investment mestic firms in a competitive manner.
in human capital (knowledge workers) is a very critical factor in Furthermore, the absorptive capacity in this study addresses how
the local people are benefiting to develop their skills through the
FDI inflows brought by multinational companies (MNCs) which locat-
E-mail addresses: elsadigmusa@yahoo.com, asadiq29@hotmail.com. ed their direct investment activities in their countries and used

0264-9993/$ – see front matter © 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.econmod.2012.04.010
EM. Ahmed / Economic Modelling 29 (2012) 1498–1504 1499

substantial economic, financial and technological incentives. More- Meanwhile, there are various possible reasons for these seemingly
over, measuring the role of absorptive capacity in determining unexpected results. Young (1991) points out that when the FDI
whether domestic firms benefit from productivity spillovers from requires adjustments in the host economy, including adjustment of
FDI should be expressed in the productivity performance of these labour allocations and quality, it takes time to take full advantage of
economies. If the economy is showing technological progress, it the potential of new technology. On the other hand, Narayanan and
means that the economy has transferred the technology of MNCs to Guan (1994) examined technology transfer in the electrical and
domestic firms and has developed human capital capacity that can electronics industries in Malaysia and find that, to have successful
be relied on to develop a productivity driven economy. This is called technology transfer, the receiving country must be ready to absorb
as the spillover effect of FDI. Otherwise, it is considered to be an new technology. In cases where labour is not ready for new technolo-
input driven economy which uses the FDI inputs to produce output gy, improvement in productivity cannot be realised with FDI. Another
without showing technical progress and less human capital skills possible reason is that, in some cases, FDI might introduce technology
development. that is obsolete in the supplying economy and that is not necessarily
more productive than technology in the host country.
1.1. FDI role in Malaysia's economic growth To close, following are some selected studies in Malaysian TFPG
which were based on growth accounting method. Starting with
Malaysia is the fourth most open economy in the world with ex- Syrquin (1991) who found that in a study between 1960 and 1989,
ports and imports accounting for most of its total gross domestic the TFP growth (TFPG) contribution was 3% for 1960–1970 and 0.5%
product (GDP). Trade was the lifeblood of the Malaysian economy. for 1980–1989. In a similar study between 1970 and 1990, Kawai
FDI has long been its backbone. Economic openness has brought (1994) found TFPG of 2.5% for 1970–1980 and 0.7% for 1980–1990.
much prosperity to this multi-racial country, as evidenced by the Similarly, Gan and Soon (1998) in their study between 1974 and
rapid pace of economic growth and development since its indepen- 1995 found TFPG contribution of 1.6% for 1974–1995 and 2.2% for
dence from Great Britain in 1957. It is noteworthy that the country's 1990–1995 and between 1980 and 1997 Ab. Wahab (2004) found
per capita income now exceeds US$4,000 mark, placing Malaysia in that TFPG contribution of 1.3% for 1990–1997. While econometric
the league of the advanced developing economies. It is pertinent to estimation studies of Wang and Thomas (1993) between 1960 and
mention in passing that Malaysia is Australia's 10th largest trading 1987 find that TFPG contribution is 2%, World Bank (1993) report be-
partner and that Australia is Malaysia's 14th largest trading partner tween 1960 and 1990 found TFPG of 1.3%, and Gan and Robinson
(Ariff, 2005). (1993) study between 1975 and 1991 found that TFP was negatively
Moreover, FDI has been hailed as the most important contributing contributed during the first half of 1980 and positively contributed
factor to Malaysia's phenomenal economic performance since the after 1985. Likewise, between 1960 and 1990 as well as between
1970s and is seen as the engine for growth, especially in the export- 1978 and 1992 Zarina and Shariman (1994) also found that TFPG
manufacturing sector. Malaysia is one of the most favoured locations has negatively contributed to Malaysia's economic growth. Therefore,
of FDI. For example in 1995, Malaysia was the second largest recipient the above-mentioned studies that were based on econometric esti-
of FDI among the Asian economies with a total amount of US$5.8 mation had a gap which had not shown the calculation of the
billion (UNCTAD, 1996). FDI has played a very important role in productivity indicator contributions and based their findings on the
shaping Malaysia's economy over its history. As the whole world is estimated coefficients of explanatory variables used to satisfy only
becoming a global village, capital would move from one area to the econometric requirements to validate and to reach homogenous
another depending on the country, which offers the highest rate of re- measures of the explanatory variables involved. On the other hand,
turn. Apart from returns from countries, other criteria that determine those studies that used growth accounting approach had calculated
the selection of FDI are; meeting the investors' needs in terms of good the productivity indicators without providing econometric results to
financial practices and the ease of moving capital. The future growth show the reliability of the results generated.
of the Malaysian economy will have to depend on the efficacy of Consequently, this study attempts to close these gaps by providing
the various policies and measures enacted by the government in statistical analysis which is lacking in the divisia translog index
order to realise her Vision 2020. More effort is now needed to attract approach (growth accounting) that is developed by Jorgenson et al.
FDI due to intense competition from emerging economies such as (1987) and proposed a combined approach of econometric and growth
Thailand, Myanmar, Indonesia and China. accounting approach to fill these two research gaps. This paper is
Furthermore, Oguci et al. (2002), state that FDI had assisted eco- aiming to investigate the degree of FDI contribution to productivity
nomic growth in many Asian countries during the 1970s and 1990s. performance in Malaysia and to inspect whether this productivity is
For example, Malaysia actively accepted foreign investment to accel- based on FDI; is human capital and absorptive capacity contribution
erate its economic growth during that period. One merit of FDI that productivity driven or input driven?
is often mentioned is technology transfer that accompanies new in-
vestments. Host economies expect direct productivity improvements 1.2. FDI spillover effects implications on sustainable productivity growth
with FDI as well as indirect spillover effects. However, the results
of empirical studies on the effects of FDI on productivity are not According to Rajneesh (2004) productivity growth among develop-
clear. For example, Oguchi (1994) compares production functions of ing countries relies considerably on the ability of their economic units
Korean and Japanese firms that were operating in the Masan free to acquire and internalise knowledge developed elsewhere if they are
trade zone and determined that Korean firms were more productive. to “catch up”. Laggard “economic units” (countries or firms) must
Ramstetter (1993) also finds that there was no significant difference possess the ability to absorb, internalise and utilise the knowledge
in the production functions of Thai local manufacturing firms and potentially made available to them. This ability is known as “absorptive
foreign firms operating in Thailand. Lichtenberg and de la Potteries capacity”, or the appropriate supply of human capital and technological
(1996) examine the effects of FDI on productivity by cross section capability to be able to generate new technologies and consequently
analysis of 13 countries and did not find significant positive effects. use productive resources efficiently. In turn, this is expected to translate
In contrast, Ramstetter compared foreign multinationals and local into productivity growth for firms as well as countries. Accordingly,
firms in Asian countries and found that foreign multinationals tended absorptive capacity is significant for development because it permits
to rate higher than local firms in many characteristics (i.e. labour domestic economic actors to internalise knowledge that exists elsewhere
productivity, capital deepening, capital productivity). Thus, empirical (either within the domestic economy or externally) that is made avail-
results on the productivity effects of FDI are not conclusive. able directly or indirectly to them. The author further explains that the
1500 EM. Ahmed / Economic Modelling 29 (2012) 1498–1504

absorptive capacity per se has slight or no influence on productivity, eco- these negative results, a new generation of studies argued that subse-
nomic growth or employment. That is, it is an inactive concept – much quent multinationals would like to prevent information leakage to
similar to an enzyme – that only has implication as a substance, serving potential local competitors. Nevertheless, to benefit from knowledge
to metabolise. Technology flows could be embodied in FDI, intermediate spillover to their local suppliers, FDI spillover ought to be between
goods, capital equipment, or licensing, but may have little or no effect on different industries. Hence, one must look for vertical (intra-industry)
development or growth without absorptive capacity. This is expressed as externalities instead of horizontal (inter-industry) externalities. In
the interaction between technology inflows and spillover effect which this regard, the externalities from FDI would patent themselves
helps the entire firms and economy to develop their technology through through forward or backward linkages, i.e., acquaintances among
the domestic firms' products which are internationally competitive as in domestic suppliers of intermediate inputs and their multinational
the case of South Korea recently. In addition, Japan has achieved its in- clients in downstream sectors (backward linkage) or between foreign
dustrial development within 30 years and has developed internationally suppliers of intermediate inputs and their domestic clients in up-
competitive firms, which had been achieved by the United States of stream sectors (forward linkage). Evidence was provided from the
America (USA) within 70 years and Europe in double this period. Simply, studies undertaken by Javorcik (2004) and Alfaro et al. (2004); for
it is because the United Kingdom (UK) has introduced industrialization instance, those studies bargain evidence for the existence of back-
process which flew to Europe, USA and the rest of the world. The spill- ward linkages between the downstream suppliers and MNEs in
over effect (absorptive capacity) which is the ability of the domestic Lithuania; and Venezuela, Chile, and Brazil, respectively. Moreover,
firms and human capital interaction with technology inflow is different paralleling the macroeconomic evidence, the study under taken
from country to country based on the human mentality and how it is by Villegas-Sanchez (2009), who has used firm level data from
going to benefit from this trend and translate it into technological Mexico, showed that domestic firms only experience productivity
progress (TFP) and to develop productivity driven economy in the form increases from FDI if they were situated in financially developed
of high quality technology and products that are able to compete in the in- regions. Meanwhile, in addition the author showed that domestic
ternational arena. In this regard, Japan is considered to be a productivity firms located in regions where access to the credit was more prob-
driven economy followed by South Korea, while, other East Asian econo- lematic would experience a negative spillover effect from FDI.
mies are considered to be input driven as they unsuccessfully failed to
translate the spillover effect of FDI to demotic technology that should 2. Methodology and estimation procedures
help the domestic firms to translate it into internationally competitive
products and investment capital. The paper attempted to modify the conventional growth account-
Additionally, Kneller and Stevens (2002) investigate whether ing framework as utilised by Stigler (1947), Abramovitz (1956),
differences in absorptive capacity (spillover effect) help to explain Kendrick (1956), and Solow (1956, 1957), which was finally brought
cross country differences in the level of productivity. Absorptive to fruition by Kendrick (1961) and further refined by Denison
capacity, as discussed in the literature by Arrow (1969), captures the (1962), Denison and Edward (1979), Griliches and Jorgenson
idea that countries may differ in their effort and ability to adopt new (1962), Jorgenson et al. (1987) and Elsadig (2006, 2007, 2008). The
technologies even if knowledge is global (Eaton and Kortum, 1999; production of the economy is expressed as a function of aggregate
Griffith et al., 2000; Papageorgiou, 2000; Xu, 2000). Two formal ap- physical capital, labour, human capital, FDI, Absorptive Capacity
proaches have been developed to model this mechanism: Abromovitz (FDI ∗ School) and time. This approach provides more room for decom-
(1986) and Cohen and Levinthal (1989) model technical adoption as position of contributions of factor inputs and technological change to
depending on the level of human capital, whereas Fagerberg (1994) economic growth.
and Verspagen (1991) develop models in which innovation improves The production function for economy can be represented as
the capacity to absorb foreign country technology. The most important follows:
factor in technology transfer is the human factor which explains the
differences in the level and concept of productivity by accessing to the GDP ¼ FðK;L;HC; FDI;AC; TÞ ð1Þ
same technology brought by FDI. Meanwhile, the benefit from absorp-
tive capacity (spillover effect) is accordingly. where aggregate output, gross domestic product (GDP) is a function
Moreover, Alfaro et al. (2009) had stated that in the macroeco- of aggregate physical capital input (K), labour input (L), human
nomics empirical literature's weak support for an exogenous positive capital (HC), foreign direct investment (FDI), absorptive capacity
effect of FDI on economic growth was originated. Moreover, the (AC) and time T, that proxies for total factor productivity growth
findings in this literature indicate that a country's capacity to take (TFPG) as a technological progress of the Malaysian economy and
advantage of FDI externalities might be limited by local conditions, indicator of spillover effects.
such as the development of local financial markets or the education The divisia index basically decomposes the output growth into the
level of the country, i.e., absorptive capacities. Borensztein et al. contribution of changes in inputs (such as aggregate physical capital,
(1998) showed that the FDI investment brings technology transfer labour, human capital, FDI and absorptive capacity growth), and
and translated it into higher economic growth only when the host TFPG. In other words, considering the data at any two discrete points
country has a minimum threshold of stock of human capital. Further, of time, say T and T-1 the growth rate of aggregate output (GDP) for
Alfaro et al. (2004) provide evidence that only countries with well- an economy can be expressed as a weighted average of the growth
developed financial markets gain significantly from FDI in terms rates of aggregate physical (K), labour (L), and FDI plus a residual
of their growth rates. These findings are consistent with the reality term typically referred to as the rate of growth of TFP. Hence the
of East Asian nations as Japan and South Korea benefited from TFPG of the economy is computed as the difference between the
foreign technology investment through technology transfer and rate of growth of aggregate output and weighted average of the
human capital skills development. growth in the aggregate physical capital, labour, FDI and absorptive
In terms of the microeconomics, empirical evidence of spillover ef- capacity where the weights are the respective shares of each input
fects of FDI, Alfaro et al. (2009) demonstrate that most of the studies in the economy's aggregate output.
using firm level panel data found that there was no effect of foreign According to Mahadevan (2001), the TFPG studies on the Malaysian
presence or resulted in a negative productivity spillover effect from manufacturing sector have used the nonparametric translog-divisia
multinational enterprises (MNEs) to the developing countries' firms. index approach developed by Jorgenson et al. (1987). This approach
Meanwhile, the positive spillover effects were found only for devel- does not require the explicit specification of a production function,
oped countries including those from East Asian nations. Based on but the major drawback is that it was not based on statistical theory
EM. Ahmed / Economic Modelling 29 (2012) 1498–1504 1501

and, hence, statistical methods could not be applied to evaluate their this data and the small shades that may not fit into our research
reliability, thus casting doubts on their results. The present study at- objectives. Another disadvantage can be that the data might be out-
tempts to close this gap by developing this model into a parametric dated. Similarly, we have no control over the quality of the data and
model and providing statistical analysis for it in the first step as follows: would not know how authentic are the measures used for data
collection.
lnGDPT ¼ a þ α: lnKT þ β: lnLT þ θ: lnHCT þ λ: lnFDIT Meanwhile, the data for this study has been collected from the
ð2Þ
þφ: lnACT þ εT T ¼ Q 1 1999  Q 4 2008 Department of Statistics of Malaysia in the form of quarterly period
of Q1 1999 to Q4 2008, of the output was quarterly real GDP and
where the inputs are physical capital, (gross capital formation as a share of
GDP), number of labour force (number of employed persons), real
α is the output elasticity with respect to physical capital FDI inflows and the school enrolment that is representing (human
β is the output elasticity with respect to labour capital) as a proxy and absorptive capacity (FDI*SCHOOL) which is
θ is the output elasticity with respect to human capital representing the interaction variable .between FDI and human capital
λ is the output elasticity with respect to FDI (absorptive capacity).
φ is the output elasticity with respect to absorptive capacity
a is the intercept or constant of the model 1 4. Results and discussion
εT is the residual term 2
ln is the natural log to transform the variables. This section demonstrates the results of the unit root test con-
ducted in this study and the coefficients obtained by applying OLS
The intercept (a) has no position in the calculation of the produc- to the data by using Eq. (2). In this regard, based on Table 1, the result
tivity indicators contribution. Consequently, a second step was pro- of the unit root test indicates that almost all of the variables are non-
posed, which calculates the contribution of productivity indicators stationary in their respective levels. While, in the first differencing on
that is transforming Eq. (2) as the variables, the null hypotheses of a unit root in the Augmented
Dickey Fuller tests were rejected at the 1% significance level. Therefore,
Δ lnTFPT ¼ Δ lnGDPT −½α:Δ lnKT þ β:Δ lnLT þ θ ::Δ lnHCT ð3Þ since all the variables have to be differenced once to obtain stationarity,
þλ:Δ lnFDIT þ φ ::Δ lnACT  it is integrated of order 1 which enables us to proceed with the rest of
the economic model. Referring to Engle and Granger (2003), if the vari-
where the weights are given by the average value shares as follows: ables have occurred in first differences instead of levels, the difficulties
of non-stationary variables could be avoided since the differenced vari-
Δ lnGDPT is the growth rate of output ables are normally stationary even if the original variables are not as
α:Δ lnKT is the contribution of the physical capital. explained by Elsadig (2006).
β:Δ lnLT is the contribution of the labour Moreover, based on Table 2, the result implies that, the coeffi-
θ ::Δ lnHCT is the contribution of the human capital cients of the effects of foreign direct investment (FDI) as both variable
λ:Δ lnFDIT is the contribution of the FDI and as proxy showed the interaction variable (FDI ∗ SCHOOL) that is
ϕ ::Δ lnACT is the contribution of the absorptive capacity used as a proxy for absorptive capacity in order to know the degree
Δ lnTFPT is the total factor productivity growth of spillover effect, school enrolment to take into account human
Δ is the difference operator denoting proportionate change rate. capital and labour force, indicating a positive effect on Malaysian
economic growth.
Accordingly, the framework decomposes growth rate of aggregate However, from the result, physical capital shows a negative
output into the contributions of the rates of growth of the aggregate relationship on Malaysian economic growth. The R² in this model
physical capital, labour, human capital, FDI and absorptive capacity, is 0.85366, which explains that 85% of the total differences in the
plus a residual term typically referred to as the rate of growth of TFP. amount of gross domestic product (GDP) can be explained by the
changes of the independent variables, which are human capital,
3. Data sources physical capital, absorptive capacity and labour force. Furthermore,
the adjusted R² 0.83693 takes into account the sample size and the
Secondary data had been collected to be used in this study. In number of independent variables included in the regression equation.
this regard, the secondary data were the data that were collected
neither directly by the user nor specifically for the user, often under
Table 1
conditions not known to the user. It may be available from internal
Augmented Dickey–Fuller coefficients, Q1 1999–Q4 2008.
sources, or might have been collected and published by another
organisation. The advantages of secondary data are that it is cheap Level First difference
and inexpensive and is easily accessible and available for the public Variable Trend and Intercept Trend and Intercept
use. Furthermore, it saves time and efforts and totally unobtrusive. intercept intercept
It avoids data collection problems and it provides a basis for compar- Physical − 1.851 (2) − 0.977 (2) − 9.056 (1)*** − 9.178 (1)***
ison. The secondary data normally could be found in various govern- capital
ments and international research institutions' statistical websites. FDI − 3.974 (4)** − 2.239 (4) − 13.447 (0)*** − 13.447 (0)***
FDI human − 3.940 (4)** − 2.867 (1)* − 13.330 (0)*** − 12.911 (0)***
The secondary data used in this study is assumed to be reliable be-
capital
cause it was prepared and published by the Department of Statistics GDP − 10.831(5)** − 0.516 (6) − 4.585 (4)*** − 4.744 (4)***
in Malaysia. On the other hand, the disadvantages of the secondary Human − 6.877 (0)*** − 0.372 (2) − 10.120 (0)*** − 6.900 (1)***
data were related to the credibility of the source who has published capital
Labour force − 4.914 (0)*** − 1.838 (1) − 11.525 (0)*** − 11.393 (0)***

Figures in the table were estimated by using the original data


1
The intercept term, as usual, gives the mean or average effect on dependent vari- Asterisk ***, **, and * denote 1%, 5%, 10% respectively. Figures in parentheses are the lag
able of all the variables excluded from the model. lengths. The asymptotic and finite sample critical values for ADF are obtained from
2
The residual term proxies for the total factor productivity growth that accounts for MacKinnon (1996). ADF test examine the null hypothesis of a unit root against the
the technological progress of the economy through the quality of input terms. stationary alternative.
1502 EM. Ahmed / Economic Modelling 29 (2012) 1498–1504

Table 2 Particularly, in the pick flow of foreign direct investment to


Estimated coefficients of Malaysian economy, Q1 1999 − Q4 2008. Malaysian economy, the TFPG contribution was very low or negative
Variables Coefficients t-Statistic Prob. and that was observed during the period of structural transformation
in Malaysian economy in 1987. The economy grew very fast based on
C − 31.95784 − 6.665074 0.0000
LABSORPTIVE 0.049329 1.228194 0.2276 FDI that supported the manufacturing sector to become the engine
LPHYCAPITAL − 0.194723 − 1.800798 0.0804 of growth of Malaysian economy during this period. The negative
LHUMANCAPITAL 0.797493 0.833973 0.4100 productivity growth of Malaysian economy which has been shown
LLABOURFORCE 4.132359 3.519926 0.0012
through the negative contrition of TFPG during the period of this
FDI 0.193961 3.228078 0.0026
study could be explained by the fact that this period is considered
R-squared 0.853656 being the period of post Asian financial crisis. During this period FDI
Adjusted R-squared 0.836930 flew out of Malaysia and reduced so much. By comparing TFPG contri-
F-statistic 51.04044 bution rates of this study with previous selected studies in Malaysia,
Prob (F-statistic) 0.000000
this study found that TFPG contribution rates are consistent with
Figures in the table were estimated by using Eq. (2). most of the previous studies as demonstrated in the introductory
part of the paper; the TFPG of Malaysia contribution was very low
or negative. Additionally, the findings of this study are very consistent
4.1. Productivity indicators contribution with the studies of Zarina and Shariman (1994), who found that TFPG
of Malaysia was negative during 1978–1992 and Gan and Robinson
Analysis was carried out to compare the productivity indicators of (1993) found that TFPG was negative during the first half of 1980
quarterly period of Q1 1999 to Q4 2008, of the output is quarterly and positive after 1985.
real GDP and the inputs are gross real capital formation, number of Meanwhile, the highest contribution of GDP to the productivity
labour force (number of employed persons), real FDI inflows and the growth (input driven) of the Malaysian economy by including human
school enrolment that is representing (human capital) as a proxy and capital, FDI inflows and absorptive capacity (FDI∗ SCHOOL) that is
absorptive capacity (FDI∗ SCHOOL) which represents the interaction representing the interaction variable between FDI and human capital
variable between FDI and human capital (absorptive capacity) within (absorptive capacity) which includes the traditional factors of produc-
the Malaysian economy for the entire period of Q1 1999 Q4 2008. tion in the model resulted in negative contribution of TFPG (Table 3).
Moreover, the use of total factor productivity overcomes the problems This period of the study was found to be the period of post Asian finan-
of single productivity indicators such as labour productivity and capital cial crisis of 1997 and the period that followed it. The performance of
deepening by measuring the relationship between output and its total the Malaysian economy was very low compared with the period after
inputs (a weighted sum of all inputs), thereby giving the residual out- the transformation of Malaysian economy into an exported-oriented
put changes not accounted for by total factor input changes. Being a re- one. The TFPG contributed negatively and the GDP was the highest
sidual, changes in TFP are not influenced by changes in the various one to contribute to the economy's input driven productivity growth
factors which affect technological progress such as the quality of factors with no technological progress that must show the positive effects the
of production, flexibility of resource use, capacity utilisation, quality of FDI inflows in terms of technology transfer and skills upgrading the
human capital and management, economies of scale, and so on and so human capital through training and retraining or what is so called
forth (Rao and Preston, 1984). learning by doing. This study found that the reasons behind input
Therefore, the improvement and slowdown of TFP contribution to driven contribution were the financial crises of 1997 that reduced FDI
Malaysian economy in terms of average annual growth rates are inflows and flew out Malaysia, besides the quality of human capital
dependent on the quality of the inputs used in the production of the and the technology involved in the production of the economy.
economy, that were reported to be of low quality and insufficient. Moreover, the contribution of aggregate physical capital to GDP
As a result of low quality inputs involved in Malaysian economic in terms of average annual productivity growth of the Malaysian
activities, the contribution of TFPG to the Malaysian economy in economy was considered to be high in the form of input driven, not
terms of average annual productivity growth by including human productivity driven as observed in the negative contribution of
capital, FDI inflows and absorptive capacity (FDI ∗ SCHOOL) which TFPG that indicated the quantity of capital that contributed to high
represents the interaction variable between FDI and human capital GDP growth, not the quality of the capital that was contributed
(absorptive capacity) in the model was negative (Table 3). On the negatively to TFPG. Likewise, the contribution of aggregate labour to
other hand, the contribution of physical capital, human capital FDI GDP in terms of average annual productivity growth of the Malaysian
inflows and absorptive capacity has improved Malaysian productivity economy was positive (Table 3), but, it has contributed negatively to
growth as an input driven economy and not productivity driven econ- TFPG. Again, it is the quality of labour which is considered being low
omy based on the negative contribution of TFPG which is considered due to the fact that Malaysia's economy is dominated by unskilled
as the technological progress of the economy through the quality of and semi-skilled labour and is facing shortage of labour.
inputs used, not the quantity of them that is considered input driven Furthermore, the contribution of the human capital, FDI and ab-
by using more inputs to produce output. sorptive capacity used in the economy was as high as the contribution
of physical capital and labour. By examining the role of human capital,
FDI and absorptive capacity to achieve productivity driven economy
Table 3
through TFPG contribution, it was found from the results that
Productivity indicators of Malaysian economy, Q1 1999–Q4 2008, %. there was a negative contribution of these variables to TFPG of the
Malaysian economy (Table 3). This indicates the input driven produc-
Productivity indicators %
tivity of Malaysia's economy through the quantities of these inputs
TFPG − 31.95 and not their qualities that resulted in positive contribution of TFPG
GDP 11.52
that is so called productivity driven which shows how the economy
Physical capital 9.863
Labour 9.201 is technologically progresses and humanely develops new skills
FDI 8.154 resulting in high products in terms of quality and quantity, thus
Human capital 8.632 firms are able to compete in the global investment.
Abortive capacity 9.879 Finally, the results of this study have shown that the productivity
Figures in the table were calculated using Eq. (3). growth of Malaysia's economy is not input driven but rather, productivity
EM. Ahmed / Economic Modelling 29 (2012) 1498–1504 1503

growth driven and is based on quantity and not the quality of inputs once Malaysian economy to be a high income and knowledge driven econ-
the results of TFPG contribution were compared. The findings of this study omy by 2020, the quality of the workforce (human capital) will make
are consistent with the studies undertaken by Lall (1995), as he states that the difference in creating productivity driven economy. The human
it is in other Asian newly industrialised countries where their productivity factor plays an essential role to interact with the technology to create
was input driven and as in the statements of Young (1992, 1995) and Kim cutting edge technology and to facilitate the economic activities to
and Lau (1994). In this respect, Sarel (1996) expressed his concerns that create new values to make the difference in the Malaysian economic
some East Asian countries might face the same fate as the Soviet Union's. fundamentals. This is what so called the FDI spillover effects. Finally,
This was because these countries had invested primarily in labour and the concept of one Malaysia will become reality if the Malaysian pu-
capital rather than in technology over the past few decades and there pils integrated in one national school system instead of the current
was no real technology transfer and much human capital development race based schools.
that could sustain the progress of the industrial development That is
called in this study the spillover effects of FDI investment. Acknowledgements

5. Conclusion and policy implications A special thank goes to Nur Hamizah Mohamed Azmi for her role
in collecting and analysing the data used in this study, to the referees
Foreign direct investment (FDI) plays a significant role in Malaysia's and the Economic Modelling Chief editor for the useful comments
economic growth from the hyper markets to electronics and electrical that improved the paper significantly.
investment. This paper analyses the effects of FDI inflow investment
in Malaysian economic growth in terms of GDP and other productivity
References
indicators. In this respect, the econometric result as the first step of the
analysis has shown that there is a positive relationship between human Ab. Wahab, M., 2004. Total Factor Productivity Growth: Survey Report. Asian Produc-
capital and absorptive capacity, those tested to know the level of the tivity Organization, Tokyo, Japan.
Abramovitz, M., 1956. Resource and output trends in the United States since 1870.
spillover effects on GDP. Whereas, the influence of the physical capital American Economic Review 46 (2), 5–23.
on Malaysia's economic growth in terms of GDP growth was found to Abromovitz, M., 1986. Catching up, forging ahead, and falling behind. Journal of
be negative and unidirectional runs were found from FDI to GDP. Economic History 46, 386–406.
Alfaro, L., Chanda, A., Kalemli-Ozcan, S., Sayek, S., 2004. FDI and economic growth: the
Moreover, this paper showed that human capital, technology
role of local financial markets. Journal of International Economics, 64 (1). Elsevier,
spillover effects and labour force provide the potential effects of FDI pp. 89–112 (October).
to enhance the Malaysian economic growth as an input driven Alfaro, L., Chanda, A., Kalemli-Ozcan, S., Sayek, S., 2009. Does Foreign Direct Investment
Promote Growth? Exploring the Role of Financial Markets on Linkages. Harvard Busi-
economy. Meanwhile, the contribution of human capital offers the
ness School, Boston, MA, USA, http://www.people.hbs.edu/lalfaro/fdiandlinkages.pdf.
strongest evidence in influencing GDP. In addition the MNEs have Ariff, M., 2005. The Drives of Competitiveness in Malaysia. Working Paper. Malaysian
played a major role in bringing economic development and employ- Institute of Economic Research, Kuala Lumpur.
ment to Malaysia and many parts of the world. Arrow, K., 1969. Classificatory notes on the production and transmission of technical.
Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 2 (2), 359–380.
Furthermore, the FDI inflows generate the possible spillovers of Borensztein, E., De Gregorio, J., Lee, J.-W., 1998. How does foreign direct investment
technology and knowledge (that determine by the level of absorptive affect economic growth. Journal of International Economics 45, 115–135.
capacity) through the interaction of technology knowledge and local Cohen, W., Levinthal, D., 1989. Innovation and learning: two faces of R&D. International
Economic Review 40, 537–570.
human capital to upgrade their skills and firms to transfer the technol- Dahlman, C., Nelson, R., 1995. Social Absorption Capability, National Innovation
ogy to the economy. This spillover effects might be able to improve the Systems and Economic Development. In: Perkins, D.H., Koo, B.H. (Eds.), Social
Malaysian firms and human capital development to contribute signif- capability and long-term growth. Macmillan Press, Basingstoke.
Denison, E.F., 1962. The sources of economic growth in the United States and the alter-
icantly to Malaysia's economic growth. As expected the production native before use. New York: A Supplementary Paper, Committee for Economic
supported by advance technology will educate the skilled labour and Development, pp. 229–255.
eventually improved the productivity and enhance the economic Denison, E.F., Edward, P., 1979. Accounting of slower economic growth; the United
States in the 1970s. The Brooking Institution, Washington.
growth to be productivity driven growth that must show technical Eaton, J., Kortum, S., 1999. International patenting and technology diffusion. Economic
progress through TFP contribution. Journal 107, 139–149.
However, the abovementioned econometric result has a gap of not Elsadig, M.A., 2006. Carbon dioxide emissions, impact on Malaysia's manufacturing
productivity growth. World Review of Science Technology and Sustainable Devel-
providing the productivity indicators and it was only based on the
opment 3 (1), 58–69.
coefficients of the quantities of inputs used. This is showing the Elsadig, M.A., 2007. Biochemical oxygen demand emissions impact On Malaysia's
homogenous measures of these variables as these were based on manufacturing productivity growth. Global Economic Review 36 (4), 305–319.
different measures. To fill this gap and the gap of growth accounting Elsadig, M.A., 2008. Foreign direct investment intensity effects on TFP intensity of
ASEAN 5 plus 2. Journal of Economic Development 33 (2), 155–166.
approach that has doubt in its result of not providing statistical Engle, R.F., Granger, C.W.J., 2003. ‘Time-series Econometrics: Cointegration and Auto-
measures to show its reliability. This paper has taken a second step regressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity’, Advanced information on the Bank of
by plugging the coefficients obtained in the modified model to calcu- Sweden Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel.
Fagerberg, J., 1994. Technology and international differences in growth rates.
late the productivity indicators used in this study. This includes the Gan, W.B., Robinson, E., 1993. Aggregate supply and wage price mechanism: some
growth rate of GDP, physical capital, labour force, human capital, implications for inflation stabilization in Malaysia. Paper Presented at HIID-ISIS
FDI and absorptive capacity contributions, which are considered to Seminar Kuala Lumpur.
Gan, W.B., Soon, L.Y., 1998. Input versus productivity driven growth: implications for
be input driven indicators. Besides, the calculation of TFP which is the Malaysian economy. In: Soon, L.Y., Shyamala, N. (Eds.), The Seventh Malaysia
indicated as the combined contribution of quality of the factors of Plan: Productivity for Sustainable Development. University Malaya Press, Kuala
production and an indicator of the technological progress that is Lumpur.
Griffith, R., Redding, S., Van Reenen, J., 2000. Mapping the two faces of knowledge.
showing the spillover effects that must transfer the technology to American Economic Review, papers and proceedings 59 (2), 29–35.
the hosting economy and upgrade the skills of its human capital, Griliches, Z., Jorgenson, D.W., 1962. Capital theory: technical progress and capital
which is called productivity driven. structure, sources of measured productivity change capital input. American Eco-
nomic Review 52 (1), 50–61.
Meanwhile, based on TFPG results of this paper, the Malaysian
Javorcik, B.S., 2004. Does foreign direct investment increase the productivity of domes-
economic growth is considered to be input driven and highly depen- tic firms? In search of spillovers through backward linkages. American Economic
dent on FDI investment. This is indicating that the FDI spillover effects Review 94, 605–627.
had insignificant impact on Malaysian economy, that was taken place Jorgenson, D.W., Gollop, F.M., Fraumenri, B., 1987. Productivity and US economic
growth. Amsterdam North Holland.
on developed nations in general and in Japan and South Korea in Kawai, H., 1994. International comparative analysis of economic growth: trade liberal-
particular. To achieve the new economic model goals in turning the ization and productivity. Developing Economies 11 (4), 373–397.
1504 EM. Ahmed / Economic Modelling 29 (2012) 1498–1504

Kendrick, J.W., 1956. Productive trends capital and labour. Review of Economics and Schultz, T.W., 1963. The Economic Value of Education. Columbia University Press, New
Statistics 38 (3), 248–257. York.
Kendrick, J.W., 1961. Productivity Trends in the United States. Princeton, Princeton. Solow, R.M., 1956. The production function and the theory of capital. Review of
Kim, Jong-II, Lau, Lawrence, 1994. The sources of economic growth of the East Asian Economics Studies XXIII, 101–108.
newly industrialised countries. Journal of Japanese and International Economies Solow, R.M., 1957. Technical change and the aggregate production function. Review of
8 (1), 235–271. Economics and Statistics 39, 312–320.
Kneller, R., Stevens, P., 2002. Absorptive capacity and frontier technology: evidence Stigler, George J., 1947. Trends in Output and Employment. National Bureau of
from OECD manufacturing industries. Presented at the NEISR/ESRC conference Economic Research, New York.
(13 September). Syrquin, Moshe, 1991. A comparative analysis of structural transformation in Latin
Lall, S., 1995. Malaysia: industrial success and the role of the government. Journal of America. In: Urrutia, Miguel (Ed.), Long-Term Trends in Latin American Economic
International Development 7 (5), 775–789. Development. Johns Hopkins University Press Para el Banco Interamericano de
Lichtenberg, F.R., de la Potteries, B.V.P., 1996. International R&D spill-over: a re- Desarrollo, Washington, D.C, pp. 81–116.
examination. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 5668. UNCTAD, 1996. World Investment Report 1996. UNCTAD, Geneva.
Mahadevan, R., 2001. Assessing the output and productivity growth of Malaysia's Verspagen, B., 1991. A new empirical approach to catching up or falling behind. Journal
manufacturing sector. Journal of Asian Economics 12 (4), 587–597. of Economic Literature 32, 1147–1175 (September).
MacKinnon, J.G., 1996. Numerical distribution functions for unit root and cointegration Villegas-Sanchez, C., (2009) FDI Spillovers and the Role of Local Financial Markets:
tests. Journal of Applied Econometrics 11, 601–618. Evidence from Mexico’, mimeo, University of Houston.
Narayanan, S., Guan, C.K., 1994. Technology transfer to malaysia: cases of electrical and Wang, Y., Thomas, V., 1993. Market supplanting versus market fostering interventions:
electronics industry in Penang Area. United Nations Development Program, Kuala China, East Asia and other developing countries. China Economic Review 4 (2),
Lumpur, Malaysia. 243–258.
OECD, 2002. Foreign direct investment for development maximising benefits, World Bank, 1993. The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy. Oxford
minimising costs. Report Published by OECD, Paris, France. University Press, New Work.
Oguchi, N., 1994. The growth of the Korean economy and foreign capital. In: Ichimurs, Xiaolun, Sun, 2002. Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Development What Do
S., Masumoto (Eds.), Econometric Models of Asia-Pacific Economics, pp. 363–500. the States Need To Do? Capacity Development Workshops and Global Forum on
Oguci, N., Amdzah, Bakar, Abidin, Shafii, 2002. Productivity of foreign and domestic Reinventing Government on Globalization, Role of the State and Enabling Environ-
firms in the Malaysian manufacturing industry. Asian Economic Journal 16 (3), ment, December 10–13, 2002, Marrakech, Morocco.
215–228. Xu, B., 2000. Multinational enterprises, technology diffusion, and host country produc-
Papageorgiou, C., 2000. Technology adoption, human capital, and growth theory, role tivity growth. Journal of Development Economics 32, 1258–1274.
of local financial markets. Journal of International Economics 64, 113–134. Young, A., 1991. A tale of two cities: factor accumulation and technical change in
Rajneesh, Narula, 2004. Understanding absorptive capacities in an “innovation systems Hong Kong and Singapore. National Bureau of Economic Research Macroeconomic
context: consequences for economic and employment growth”. Prepared for the Annual 7, 13–54.
ILO background paper for the World Employment Report 2004. Young, A., 1992. A tale of two cities: factor accumulation and technological change in
Ramlee, Mustapha, Abu, Abdullah, 2004. Malaysia transitions toward a knowledge- Hong Kong and Singapore. National Bureau of Economic Research, Macroeconom-
based economy. The Journal of Technology studies XXX (3) (Summer). ics Annual, pp. 13–54.
Ramstetter, E.D., 1993. Production technology in foreign and local firms in Thai Young, A., 1995. The Tyranny of numbers: confronting the statistical realities of the
manufacturing. Discussion Paper No. 8. Graduate School of International Develop- East Asian growth experience. Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, 641–680.
ment, Nagoya University, Nagoya, Japan. Zarina, Z.A., Shariman, A., 1994. Growth, Inflation and Potential Output. Central Bank
Rao, P.S., Preston, R.S., 1984. Inter-factor substitution, economic of scale, and technical Discussion Paper 33, Kuala Lumpur.
change: evidence from Canadian industries. Empirical Economics 9 (4), 247–262.
Sarel, M., 1996. Growth in East Asia: what we can and cannot infer. IMF Working Paper
95/98. International Monetary Fund, Washington DC.

View publication stats

You might also like