You are on page 1of 27

Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

Innovation Diffusion in
Developing Countries:
An Extension of Bass-Model
in the Context of International Marketing

by

Dr. Sein Min


Research Fellow

UNIVERSITÄT PASSAU
Lehrstuhl für Betriebswirtschaftslehre
mit Schwerpunkt Absatzwirtschaft und Handel
Prof. Dr. Dr. h.c. Helmut Schmalen

August 2001

1
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries:

An Extension of Bass-Model in the Context of International Marketing

Introduction
Innovation diffusion has been interested by many academic disciplines including
anthropology, (rural-, and medical -) sociology, education, economics, communication,
geography, etc.1 Martketing is also one of the disciplines being much interested in the nature
of innovation diffusion. as it has to deal with introducing new technological products into the
markets. Understanding it can help marketing managers to forecast sales of new products and
to formulate their marketing strategies. Todays, international marketing is executed by many
firms and hence markets of developing and least developed countries are more and more
interesting. For the task of internatioanl marketing which has a special interest in developing
markets, studies of innovation diffusion can help a lot.
The phenomena of innoation diffusion is studied at two levels: micro individual level
(adoption process) and macro aggregate level (diffusion process).2 Diffusion process is
observed with the help of models, i.e. modeling approach is used to capture the reality of
diffusion process. Diffusion models used in marketing area are particularly interested in how
diffusion occurs in the consumer domain.3 Thus, these models can or should relate to the
theoretical aspects of consumer behaviour in adopting innovations. Gatignon and Roberston
pointed out that „an integration of the behavioural and modeling literatures on diffusion could
be benieficial to both constttuenices“.4
In modeling the pattern of innovation diffusion, the Bass model was very successful
showing the high magnitude of fitness of the model.5 The Bass model reflects the individual
adoption behavior in two different ways: innovation and imitation. The model’s parameters p
and q represents the external influence to adopt (in other words, the propensity to innovate)
and the internal influence to adopt (in other words, the propensity to imitate) respectively.6

1
Mahajan, V. and M:E.F. Schoeman, „Generalized Model for the Time Pattern of the Diffusiom Process“, IEEE
Transactions on Enginerring Management, Feb. 1977, pp. 12-18., p. 12. See also Gatignon, H. and T.S.
Robertson, „ A propositional Inventory for New Diffusifon Research“, Journal of Consumer Research, Vol. 11,
March 1985, pp. 849-867, p. 849.
2
The lengthy discussion about this is found in: Rogers, M. „Diffusion of Innovations“, New York , The Free
Press, 1995.
3
Gatignon, H. and T.S. Robertson, Ibid, p. 849.
4
Ibid.
5
Bass, F. M. „A New Product Growth Model for Consumer Durables“, Management Science, 15(1969), pp.
215-2127.
6
Gatignon, H., J. Eliashberg and T.S. Robertson, „Modeling Multinational Diffusion Patterns: An Efficient
Methology“, Marketing Science, 8(1989, pp. 231-247, p. 232. The discussion on interpretation of the parameters

2
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

The Bass model was tested in the actual diffusions of products, mostly consumer durables.7 It
was also extended or modifed to overcome its assumptions by introducing such variables as
market potential, marketing-mix (advertising, price), effects of multiple products, etc.8
Diffusion researches via modeling which involve both Bass type and non-Bass type models
were increasing. The Bass model was earlier applied in a single market, mostly of U.S. Later
the application was extended to include European (industrialzed countries). There were also
investigations of the Bass-model in international setting. Nowadays, the diffusion research
covers almost the entire world and it has reached even the stage of global diffusion research.
For example, Dekimple et al conducted the research on diffusion of cellular phone comprising
184 countries, although their approach used a differnt modeling method by employing a
hazard function.9
Although the diffusion research becomes an international and global research, little
attention has been paid to the distinct nature of diffusion process in developing countries.
Dekimpe et al. criticized this point sharply as:
„The set of countries considered in most international diffusion research is not
only limited in scope, but also severely biased towards the study of industrialized
countries.10 Little is known, however, about the nature of the diffusion process in
developing countries.11 ..more research is needed on the extent of an internatioanl
learning effect (cf. Infra) both among developing countries, and between developed and
developing countries.“12
Developing countries should be paid attention by intrnational and global marketers as
well as diffusion researchers, because the developing countries (and also least developed
countries) are the major part of world market at least in terms of population. Due to market
saturation in domestic markets and increased competition among suppliers of industrial
products the markets of developing countries play increasingly an important role. Thus, it is

p and q, see Schnmlen, H. and H. Xander, „Produkteinführung und Diffusion“, in S. Albers and A. Hermann
(ed.),“Handbuch Produktmanagement: Strategieenwicklung – Produktplanung – Organisation – Kontrolle“,
Gabler, 2000.The criticism on Bass Model was discussed in many literatures. For examples, see Schmalen, H.
„Das Bass-Modell zur Diffusionsforschung: Darstellung, Kritik und Modifikation“, ZfBf 41(3/1989), pp. 210 –
226, Tanny, S.M. and N. A. Derzko, „Innovators and Imitators in Innovation Diffusion Modelling“, Journal of
Forecasting, Vol. 7, 1988, pp.225-234.
7
Mahajan, V. E. Muller and F.M. Bass, „New Product Diffusion Models in Marketing: A Review and Directions
for Research“, Journal of Marketing, 54(1990), pp. 1-26, p.16 (Table 4)
8
See Ibid, p. 10-15.
9
Dekimpe, M.G., P.M. Parker and M. Sarvary, „Comparing Adoption Patterns: A Global Approach“, Working
Paper (96/37/MKT), INSEAD; 1996.
10
Dekimpe, M.G., P.M. Parker and M. Sarvary, „Multi-Market and Global Diffusion“, Working Paper,
INSEAD, 1998, p.3.
11
Ibid.
12
Ibid. p.4.

3
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

necessary to pay a close attention towards the diffusion process in developing countries. This
effort should include specific theoretical consideration about the developing countries and
diffusion there and then the development of appropriate models for them. Moreover, we need
to pay attention towards these countries because of the changing condition in the world such
as globalization.
In this paper, we are going to present the development of a diffusion model which is
extended from the popular Bass model based on behavioural argument of adoption in these
countries. Before we present our model, there will be a review about the international difusion
research and cross-country diffusion models. After the extended model for developing
counties has been described, we will continue to test the model by using data of a developing
country. We have selected Myanmar for this purpose compiling data of computer, room air-
conditioner, TV-set and telephone for the period 1985-2000. As required in the model, we
will use Japan as a lead country. For this, we have collected the statistics of per capita TV
and telephone possession extracting out of the UN Statistical Yearbooks. In the empirical
study, we first plot the data and estimate the parameters using OLS method and nonlinear
least square (NLS) estimation method with the help of SPSS software. Finally, we present the
conclusion and implications from our study.

Review of International Diffusion Research


The very well.known Bass model has been used to study diffusion of innovations
including new ideas, new products and new technologies. These studies focused on each
individual country. It is interesting however to compare and conclude whether there are some
systematic djfferences in characteristics of diffusion process of countries under study. This
task was done by the estimation and analysis of parameters of Bass diffusion model. Some
scholars applied a form of econometric model to include some exogeneous variables. A new
phase of international diffusion research began with incorporating lead-leg effect into a basic
diffusion model.13
Heeler and Hustad studied in 1980 the Bass model with international data.14 They
believed that the use of Bass model in international setting cannot guarantee its success
because of environmental differences like government policy and trade restrictions. They

13
Summary of International Diffusion Studies is found in; Dekimpe, M.G., P.M. Parker and M. Sarvary, „Multi-
Market and Global Diffusion“, Working Paper (98/73/MKT), INSEAD, 1998.
14
Heller, R. M. and T.P. Hustad „Problems in predicting New Product growth for Consumer Durables“,
Management Science, 26 (1980), pp. 1007-1020. .

4
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

found that the results showed instability with limited data and systematic underreporting of
estimated time to attain peak level of first purchase sales. 15
To search cross-national differences in diffusion processes between the home market
and foreign markets, Takada and Jain conducted an investigation of parameters of Bass
diffusion model in the Pacific Rim Region comprising US, Japna, Korea and Taiwan.16 The
diffusion process starts usually in US and later the rest countries subsequently follow the
process. Thus, there exists a phenomena of lead-lag effect. They explained the cross-national
differences due to two types effects: country effect and time effect. Especially due to latter,
they expected that lag countries would have a faster rate of diffusion. Their empirical study
could confirm this proposition.
As an application of diffusion knowledge into international marketing, Helsen et al.
tried to segment the countries based on diffusion parameters.17 They investigaed whether
diffusion parameters of one country-cluster differ from those of others. Their findings
indicated that, for all practical purposes, little agreement exists between the traditional-
derived country segements and diffusion-based segements.18 However, they proposed to
actually segement the countries on the basis of how the diffusion process evolves within these
countries for various consumer durables. 19
Attempts have benn also made to explain the differences in parameters of diffusion
model among countries. Gatignon et al. developed an econometric model for the diffusion of
innovations at the individual country level.20 In their model four factors were considered:
cosmopolitanism, mobility and women in the labour force. Their studies included 14
European countries and adoptions of six consumer durables. The major finding was that
cosmopolitansim is related positively to the population propensity to innovate for the six
products studied. By determining the parameters‘ values based on other exogeneous factors it
makes possible to forecast sales of one country based on the experiences of other countries.21
There were also studies which extended the scope of the internatioanl diffusion
research by relating one country’s diffusion with others. The relationship among countries in
this respect can be classified into (1) reciprocal relationship (mutual effect) and (2) one way

15
More specifically, they found that stable and reasonably accurate predictions of the peak year of sales only
occur with at least ten years of input data, generally after the peak has already occured.
16
Takada, H. and D. Jain, „Cross National Analysis of Diffusion of Consumer Goods in Pacific Rim Countries“,
Journal of Marketing, 55 (1991), pp. 48-57.
17
Helsen, K. K. Jedidi, K. and W.S. DeSarbo, „A New Approach to Country Segmentation utilizing
Multinational Diffusion Patterns“, Journal of Marketing, 57(1993), pp. 60-71..
18
Ibid. p. 69
19
Ibid. p. 62.
20
Gatignon, H., J. Eliasherrg and T.S. Robertson, Op. cit.
21
Ibid. p.245.

5
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

relationship (lead-lag effect). The reciprocal relationship among countries in the international
diffusion process was expressed by Mahajan et al. with special emphasis on unification of
European community.22 Their study however did not empirically base upon the model. They
produced the different parameter values among EU member countries which varied across
countries
The one-way effect in terms of led-lag relationship was explored by Ganesh and
Kumar23 and Ganesh et al.24. They put forward the concept of „learning effect“ which reflects
that when a new product/technology is introduced in one country and with a time lag in
subsequent countries, there exists an opportunity for consumers in the lag countries to learn
from the experience of the lead country adopters.25 The „learning effect“ was discovered by
Ganesh and Kumar for industrial technological product (retail scanner). In this study the
existence of learning effect was confirmed but the size was not homogeneous. In similar way,
Ganesh et al. investigated empirically for consumer durables (Home Computers, Microwave
Ovens, Cellular Phones and VCRs). This study, conducted for consumer durables in selected
Euopean countries, showed that there existed a cross-country learning effect that was a
function of cultural similarity, economic similarity, time-lag, type of innovation and existence
of technical standard but not of geographic proximity.26 All these two studies used basically
the model proposed by Peterson and Mahajan27 in order to systematically capture the learning
effect. In their study of consumer durables, they linked the coefficient of lerning effect with
covariables mentioned abouve.
Dekimpe et al. had interestingly investigated the breadth of adoption or variabilityin
adoption timing across countries.28 They distinguished the global diffusion process into
breadtn and depth dimensions. The dynamic of diffuson within a country is termed as depth
process. Their model used a hazard function, which gives the adoption rate of a country
during a particular time interval. Subsequently they used a general relationship between a
distribution’s hazard and survivor function. The parameters were estimated through maximum

22
Mahajan, V. and E. Muller, „Innovation Diffusion in Borderless Global Market: Will the 1992 Unification of
the European Community Accelerate Diffusion of New Ideas, Products and Technologies“, in Technological
Forcasting and Social Change, 45 (1994), pp. 221-237.
23
Ganesh, J. and V. Kumar, „Capturing the Cross-national Learning Effect: An Analysis of an Industrial
Technology Diffusion“, Journal of the Academy of Marketing Research, 24 (1996), pp. 328-337.
24
Ganesh, J., V. Kumar and V. Subramaniam, „Learning Effect in Multinational Diffusion of Consumer
Durables: An Exploratory Investigation“, Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 25 (1997), pp. 214-228.
25
Ganesh, J. and V. Kumar, Op. cit. p.330.
26
The lack of support for this proposition does not mean that geographical distance is unimportant in
influencing the learning process but, rather, that the other factors probably play a greater role. Ibid. p. 223.
27
Peterson, R.A. and V. Mahajan, „Multi-Product Growth Models“, in Research in Marketing ed.. Jagdish
Sheth, Green wich, CT: JAI Press, 1978.
28
Dekimpe, M.G., P.M. Parker and M. Sarvary, „Globalization: Modeling technology adoption timing across
countries“, Working Paper (96/38/MKT), INSEAD, 1996.

6
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

likelihood function. The adoption rate was the function of endogenous and exogenous factors.
They considered the importance of endogenous demonstration effect exerted by earlier
adoptions in „similar“ countries. The exogenous factors were political disposition (communist
or not), socioeconomic characteristics (GNP per capita, crude death rate, population growth),
social system homogenity (number of ethniic groups) and population concentration (number
of major population centers). To illustrate the model, data from cellular telephone industry of
184 countries were collected. The findings supported the extant theories of cross-country
adoption. The demonstration effect of earlier adoptions was also accepted. Similar approach
was also applied by Dekimpe et al to explain the global diffusion of network innovations, i.e
Telecom.29 But they argued that gloabal adoption is comprised of two stages: implementation
and confirmation. The models of the same type were developed to investigate the diffusion
proceess in each country. Their approach was applied for the study of 160 countries.
From these and other studies, a few generalizations seem to emerge about the cross-
country diffusion Dekimpe et al. summarized them as follows:30
(1) The wealth of a country (mostly operationalized through GNP/ capita) has a postive effect
on diffusion process.
(2) There are cross-national learning effects. Countries whcih introduce the innovation a later
point in time seem to have faster with-in country diffusion patterns.
(3) The size of cross-region experience effect is not homogeneous. There was no uniform
finding about the relationship between geographic proximity and learning effect.
(4) The social system heterogeneity has a negative effect of diffusion for both timing and
speed of diffusion of a country.

Cross-country Diffusion Models


Earlier studies of diffusion models focused on a single country, mostly using the Bass
diffusion model. Marketing research on multinational diffusion process has been relatively
sparse in 1980s.31 In 1990s, however, the attention had been paid towards to cross-country
diffusion process, i.e. the diffusion process among countries. In markeing literature the
underlying phenomenon of international diffusion has been observed under the concept of

29
Dekimpe, M.G., P.M. Parker and M. Sarvary, „Global Diffusion of Network Technologies: A Double-Hazard
Approach“, Working Paper (97/50/MKT), INSEAD, 1997.
30
Dekimpe, M.G., P.M. Parker and M. Sarvary, „Multi-Market and Global Diffusion“, Op. cit, p. 8-9.
31
Helsen, K., Jeddi; K. and W.S. DeSarbo, „A new Approach to Country Segmentation Utilizing Multinational
Diffusion Patterns“, Journal of Marketing, 57, (1993), pp. 60-71.

7
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

international product cycle.32 The models were not developed for this purpose, while studies
on international diffusion were increasingly conducted by introducing relevant economic,
soical and cultural variables into the diffusion parameters of individual countries.
In 1978 Peterson and Mahajan constructed a model for diffusion of multi-products
which have interrelationships among them. 33 This model was not orginally intended to apply
in the multicountry markets, but the structure of model is applicable for cross-country
diffusion process, since it has based on the lead-lag phenemenon.34 The model appears as
follows:

dX/dt = (p1 + q1 X) (N1- X)


dY/dt = [p2 + (q2 + 2X) Y] (N2 –Y)
dZ/dt = [p3+ (q3 + 3Y) Z] (N3–Z)

These equations can be explicitly assigned to particular countries. For example, X is


for US, Y is for Japan and Z is for Korea. US is the lead country and Japan is firstly the lag
country, but later it becomes the lead country for Korea. The coefficients s are termed as
lead effect.35
Another diffusion modeling application in a multinational setting was provided by
Eliashber and Helsen. They expanded the Bass-model to reflect the lead-lag phenomena by
incorporating a term that captures the impact of the diffusion in the lead market.36 Mahajan,
Muller, and Kalish used a similar version of the model to analyze whether firms should
launch their product in all their target markets simultaneously („sprinkle djffusion strategy) or
sequentially („waterfall“ strategy).37.
The cross-country diffusion process was considered for longer time in German
literature. Sartorious38 applied one kind of diffusion model in the combined markets where
every country has a reciprocal effect on diffusion of other countries. The diffusion model was

32
Vernon, R. „International Investment and International Trade in the Product Cycle“, in:Quarterly Journal of
Economics, Vol. 80, No.2, (May 1966), pp. 190-207. See also Wells, L.T. Jr. „International Trade: The Product
Life Cycle Approach“, in: Wells, L.T. Jr. (ed.) „The Product Life Cycle and International Trade“, Boston, 1972.
33
Peterson, R.A. and V. Mahajan, Op. cit.
34
Takada, H. and D. Jain, Op. cit.
35
Ibid. p.52.
36
Helsen, K. et al., Op. cit. p. 63. See also Eliashberg, J.and K. Helsen, „Cross-country Diffusion Processes and
Market Entry Timing“, Working Paper, University of Pennsylvania, 1987 and Eliashberg,, J. and K. Helsen,
„Modeling lead/lag Phenomena in Global Marketing: The case of VCRs“, Working Paper, University of
Pennsylvania, 1996.
37
Ibid. p.63, See also Mahajan, V., E. Muller and S. Kalish, „Waterfall and Sprinkler New-Product Strategies in
Competitive Global Markets“, Working Paper, University of Texas at Austin, 1990 or Kalish, S., V. Mahajan
and E. Muller, (the same title) in International Journal of Research in Marketing, 1995, pp. 105-120.
38
Sartorious, B. „Exportmarkeing ffür neuartige Gebrauchsgüter auf verbundenen Märkten“, Dissertation,
Universität Passau, 1983.

8
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

named as Schmalen model39 which has its root in Bass model despite it applies the
compartment system dividing the potential market into innovator segement and imitator
segement. Both Schmalen and Sartorious used their models for the normative purpose of
searching optimal strategies of markeing-mix rather than for the purpose of sales
forecasting.40
Min considered the diffusion process between developed and developing countries
with lead-lag phenomenon, viz. developed countries as lead countries and developing
countries as lag countries.41 The model for diffusion process was constructed accordingly to
include the lead effect of developed countries. Despite the same principle of lead-lag
relationship, his argument was based on cosumer behaviour. It was postulated that in
developing countries consumer categories with respect to adoption of an innovation could be
distisnguished into three types, namely innovators, imitators and international imitators.42
International imitators are imitators whose orientation to imitate is however towards outside
their society, specifically international spreadness and acceptance of the innovation. As
discussed by many authors, developing countries can be characterized by „dualism“
consisting of rich people on one side and poors on the other side. A portion of rich people
who are educated, cosmopolited and internationally outlooked, always try to copy the
lifestyles of people in other countries, especially in advanced countries.43 They are of course
modern elite of rich people and they can play the role of a change agent demonstrating the
innovation in their surroundings, thus the process of diffusion is accelerated. Hypothetically,
they may be pushing the adoption and diffusion process more effectively than innovators.
Mahajan and Muller proposed the model which takes into account the reciprocal
effects of innovation diffusion among member countries of an economic integration.44 The
framework was particularly taken for the unification of European Community in 1992. They
recommended that this unification effort would make faster the diffusion of ideas, products
and technologies, Their model has the following structure:45

39
Schmalen, H. „Marketing-Mix für neuartige Gebrauchsgüter“, Gabler, Wiesbaden, 1979.
40
See. also Schmalen, H. „Markteröffnungssstrategien für Neuheiten“, in ZfB, 41, March 1989, pp. 210-226.
41
Min, Sein „Exportmarketing im Wirtschaftsverkehr zwischen Industrie- und Entwicklungsländern: Eine
computer gestützte Simulationsanalyze zur Ermiitlung optimaler Strategien für die abzatzpolitischen
Instrumente“, Dissertation, Universität Passau, 1990.
42
Ibid. p. 62-63.
43
Ibid. p. 62.
44
Mahajan, V. and E. Muller, „Innovation Diffusion in a Borderless Global Market: Will the 1992 Unification of
the European Community Accelerate Difuusion of New Ideas, Products and Technologies“, Technological
Forecasting and Soical Change, 45, (1994), pp. 221-237.

9
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

dX/dt = ( a + b X + q Y ) (N – X)
M+N M+N

dY/dt = ( p + q Y + b X ) (N – Y)
M+N M+N

The extended elements in the adpotion rates of respective countries denote the
incremental contributions to the rates of diffusion. They explained: „By supporting a border-
free zone of market potential size (M+N), unification permits potential customers and
individual adopters in two countries to travel, trade, shop, and settle anywhere in the union.
Because of this freedom, it is reasonable to assume that adopters from each country are also
likely to influence the remaining potential adopters in the other country.“ 46
In the study of cross-country diffusion of industrial technology (retail scanners)
Ganesh and Kumar formulated a diffusion model based on the multi-product model of
Peterson and Mahajan.47 They called it as „learning model“. 48

d F1(t) = [p+q*F1(t)+c*F2(t)]*[1 _ F1(t)]


dt

where
F1(t) = N1(t)]/ m1 = the cumulative penetration ratio till time t for the lag country
F2(t) = N2(t)]/ m2 = the cumulative penetration ratio till time t for the lead country
p = the coefficient of innovation for the lag country
q = the coefficient of imitation for the lag country
c = the learning coefficient for the lag country

In the same study they formulated another version that excluded the innovation coefficient,
thus including only the coefficients of imitation and learning. They assumed that in the lag countries,
the diffusion of industrial technological innovation was seldom shaped by the innovativeness there.
They named their model as „pure learning model“.49

d F1(t) = [q*F1(t)+c*F2(t)]*[1 _ F1(t)]


dt

Ganesh et. al. captured the learning effect by studying diffusion of consumer durables, but the
model used was a little different from the (previous) work of Ganesh and Kumar. The model of
Ganesh et al. oriented more towards the model of Mahajan and Muller for „borderless markets“.50 The

45
Mahajan V. and E. Muller, Op. cit. p. 224.
46
Ibid.
47
Peterson, R.A. and V. Mahajan, Op. cit.
48
Ganesh, J and V. Kumar, „Capturing the Cross-National ................“, Op. cit., p. 332.
49
Peterson, R.A. and V. Mahajan, Op. cit. p. 333.
50
Mahajan, V. and E. Muller, Op. cit.

10
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

model formulation was different from their „learning model“ in the way that the learning effect varies
with not only the dynamic influence of the market saturation level in the lead country but also the
market potentials of lead and lag countries. This model can be expressed as follows:51

d F1(t) = [p+q*F1(t)+c*(m1/m2)*F2(t)]*[1 _ F1(t)]


dt

where
m1 = market potential of the lag country
m2 = market potential of the lead country

Modeling Cross-Country Diffusion Process between Developed Countries and


Developing Countries (Extension of the Bass Model)
Although the diffusion research has been extended towards the global context, there
has been not yet a particular research conducted for developing countries. Accordingly we
could not find distinct models which were formulated particularly for developing countries.
As Dekimpe et al. reviewed52, little is known about the nature of the diffusion process in
developing countries. However, the lead-lag phenomenon as focused by international
diffusion studies can be directed towards the cross-country diffusion process between
developed countries and developing countries. Now we will focus on building an appropriate
model which will focus on developing countries in the context of international diffusion.
When we stage the diffusion process into developed and developing countries,
developed counties act usually as leader whilst the latter as follower. We can assume that
although the extent of diffusion in developed countries will cause an impact on that in
developing countries, the reverse does not occurm in general. As explained earlier, the impact
will increase the adoption rate of innovation through resulting in international imitation or in
ohter word „demonstration effect“,. Thus, we add a new component in the rate of adoption
that reflects incremental rate by international influence as the following:

dX/dt = [p + q (X/M) + r (X*/M*)}[M – X]

where p, q = innvation and imitation coefficient respectively


X = cummulative number of adoption in time t
M = market potential
X*/M* = Level of saturation in lead country, i.e. Industrialized country in time t
r = the coefficient of international influence or the coefficient of international imitation

51
Ganesh, J., V. Kumur and V. Subramaniam, Op. cit. p. 221
52
Dekimpe, M. G., P. M. Parker and M. Sarvary, „Multi_Market und Global Diffusion“, Op. cit. p. 3.

11
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

This model is of course an extension of the typical Bass model. This formulation is as
the same as the model used by Ganesh and Kumar („learning model“) in investigating the
industrial technology diffusion. The difference, however, is in theoretical point- of - view and
the interpretation of the new coefficient ( r ). We call the demonstration effect or international
imitation effect, while Ganesh and Kumar termed this phenomen as lerning effect. We believe
that although both are acceptable, the lerning effect is more appropriate for industrial
technology diffusion and the demontration effect is more suitable for consumer durables.
According to the model shown above, it can be expected that the greater „r“ the faster is the
speed of the diffusion process in developing countries. The increasing extent or level of
saturation in developed countries also raises that speed. As a variation of this basic model, we
can introduce a new variable () for time lag in peception of the innovation diffusion in
external environment (lead country) by potential adopters in developing countries.

dX/dt = [p + q (X/M) + r (X*/M*)t-}[M – X]

where  = time lag;  = 0, 1, 2, 3, ....

Empirical Study
In order to test the appropriateness of the proposed extended Bass model for the
developing countries, we will use data of innovation diffusion in a developing country.
Firstly we will estimate the parameters of Bass model. It is also necessary to have data of
diffusion in an industrialized country to investigate the existence of demonstration effect.
After getting the required data, we will estimate parameters of our extended model for the
same data. Then we will ask ourselves whether the Bass model fits in a setting of developing
country and whether the parameter values lie in normal ranges. For the extended model too,
we will investigate whether the extended model fits with actual data and whether there exists
actually the demonstration or learning effect between developed countries and developing
countries.
Data
We collected annual import volume and units of four consumer durables, namely
computer, room air-conditioner, television set and telephone which were imported into
Myanmar53 during the period from 1985-86 to 1999-2000. Because there was no standard

53
Myanmar is officially a least developed country (LDC). Myanmar can be however considered as a developing
country in general.

12
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

publication of data we required, the statistics of import items produced by the Custom Office
were reviewed and collected by the Central Statistical Organization (CSO) in Yangon. Since
Myanamr did not produce these products domestically or if so as in the case of television, it is
negligible, we can assume that the units imported represent the number of adoption for each
consumer durables. The imported volume is expressed in thousands of Ks which is Myanmar
currency. The rate of convrsion between the CIF value in US dollar to Myanmar currency was
not changed significantly over the time, we have already excluded the effect of inflation of the
Myanamr currency.54 Assuming that the prudcts‘ prices denominated in US$ were stable
during the observed time, we think that it is possible to use these data as an alternative to
units. The following table (Tab. 1) shows the import of selected consumer durables for the
period 1985 – 2000. Unfortunately data in units of room air-conditioner and telephone for the
period from 1985- 86 to 1991-1992 are not available. But we estimate them by average value
per unit of the period from 1992-93 to 1999-2000 for which complete data are available. The
estimated data are shown in the brackets. Among the data, it is noticable that the imports of
computers and telephone in the begining of 90s were dropped substantially. It might be due to
the political situation in Myanmar, particularly the turmoil in 1988 and consequently the
siezure of the State’s power by the present military government. .
When we plot the data as shown in Fig. 1, we get different pattterns of diffusion; we
cannot see typical pattern with peak point in almost all products except air-conditioner in Ks.
value. Moreover, very irregular amounts have been seen in telephone both Ks. value and
units.
Regarding with the diffusion of innovatioan in industrialized countries, we took the
data of Japan (lead country), because there are many cultural, economic and trade
relationships between Japan and Myanmar.The consumer durables under study were imported
mainly from Singapore, Japan.and Korea. Moreover, Japan is more or less playing a leading
role to the Far-east and South-east Asian countries. We collected thus the data of innovation
diffusion in Japan. From the UN Statistical Yearbook it is possible to compile two cultural
and communication indicators: possession of TV per 1000 inhibitants and Telephone per 100
inhibitants. We will use these data as time-varying variable that reflects increasing pressure of
international product acceptance inducing potential adopters in developing countries to adopt
the innovation, i.e. international demonstration effect. 55The two diffusion patterns of Japan
for TV and telephone are shown in the following Tab. 2 and Fig. 2.

54
The official exchange rate was 1 US$ = 6 Ks.
55
The statistics thus show the level of market saturation denoted as (X*/M*) t.

13
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

Tab. 1: Diifusion of Innovative Consumer Durables in Burma (from1985-86 to 1999-2000)*


Computer Air-conditioner TV Telephone
Ks Unit Ks. Unit Ks. Unit Ks Unit
1985-86 0 0 6480 n.a.(1536) 37042 20685 1017 n.a.(216)
1986-87 142 15 11814 n.a.(2600) 31116 7270 2291 n.a.(487)
1987-88 948 33 10744 n.a.(2546) 33142 11048 726 n.a.(154)
1988-89 651 37 2267 n.a.(537) 28238 11910 2153 n.a.(458)
1989-90 1138 152 9417 n.a.(2232) 23092 7477 1 n.a.(0)
1990-91 2342 74 10714 n.a.(2539) 97670 52740 0 n.a.(0)
1991-92 211 24 13450 n.a.(3187) 90525 55207 67 n.a.(14)
1992-93 5236 2863 17012 2079 86688 65234 331 738
1993-94 13569 6939 23782 8928 110213 69935 2526 10269
1994-95 13908 6467 35475 4612 147546 65122 3575 414
1995-96 29068 16540 43212 26024 111418 107462 281 33
1996-97 31603 54221 69013 26943 43274 33619 6537 1280
1997-98 32678 54830 97081 18190 2297 13235 12171 2061
1998-99 41895 41840 139680 40746 124228 86959 16203 2647
1999-2000 51837 71051 83295 36979 107952 101003 1264 476
*Ks in thousands
.n.a. = not available and (....) = estimated units
Source: compiled by the Central Statistical Organization (CSO), Yangon, Myanmar

14
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

Fig. 1: Diffusion Patterens of Selecdted Consumer Durables in Myanmar

Computer (Ks.) Computer (Units)


60000 80000
50000
Ks. (,000)

60000
40000

Units
30000 40000
20000 20000
10000
0 0

86-87

88-89

90-91

92-93

94-95

96-97

98-99
86-87

88-89

90-91

92-93

94-95

96-97

98-99
Year Year

Air-conditioner (Ks.) Air-conditioner (Units)


150000
50000
Ks. (,000)

100000 40000

Units
30000
50000 20000
10000
0
0
85-86

87-88

89-90

91-92

93-94

95-96

97-98

99-00

85-86

87-88

89-90

91-92

93-94

95-96

97-98

99-00
Year Year

15
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

TV-set (Ks.) TV-set (Units)


200000 120000
100000

Ks. (,000)
150000
Ks. (,000)

80000
100000 60000
40000
50000 20000
0
0

85-86

87-88

89-90

91-92

93-94

95-96

97-98

99-00
85-86

87-88

89-90

91-92

93-94

95-96

97-98

99-00
Year Year

Telephone (Ks.) Telephone (Units)


20000 12000
10000
15000
Ks. (,000)

8000

Units
10000 6000
4000
5000 2000
0 0
85-86

87-88

89-90

91-92

93-94

95-96

97-98

99-00

0
-8

-8

-9

-9

-9

-9

-9

-0
85

87

89

91

93

95

97

99
Year Year

16
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

Tab. 2:
Innovation Diffusion in Japan
(TV and Telephone)
TV Telephone
(per 1000 (per 100 inhibitants)
Year
inhibitants)
1985 579 55.5
1986 n.a. n.a.
1987 n.a. 39.7
1988 n.a. 41.1
1989 610 42.6
1990 611 44.1
1991 613 45.4
1992 614 46.4
1993 618 47.1
1994 681 47.9
1995 684 48.7
1996 683 48.9
1997 686 47.9
Source: Statistical Yearbooks, UN

Fig. 2: Innovation Diffusion of TV and


Telephone in Japan
0,8
Market Saturation (%)

0,7
0,6
0,5
0,4
0,3 TV
0,2 Telephone
0,1
0
1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

Parameter Estimation
Bass Model
We estimate firstly the parameters of Bass-model, namely p (the coefficient of
external coefficient), q (the coefficient of internal coefficient) and m (the market potential).
The market potential can be also determined from other exogenous sources of information
rather than from the diffusion model and as a result better results of estimation for p and q can

17
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

be obtained.56 For the estmation of all three parameters in Bass model, it is possible to use
different estimation methods. They are:57
1. The ordinary least squares (OLS) procedure (Bass 1969)58
2. The maximum likelihood estimation (MLE) procedure (Schmittlein and Mahajan 1982)59
3. The nonlinear least squares (NLS) procedure (Srinivasan and Mason 1986)60
4. The algebraic estimation (AE) procedure (Mahajan and Sharma1985)61

The fourth method, the algebraic estimation method, is to be used when no prior data is
available. Mahajan and Sharma developed the estimation method by which the parameters
p and q of the Bass model are estimated. It requires however information from managers
about three items: (1) the market size (m), (2) the time of the peak of the noncummulative
adoptioin curve, and (3) the adoption level at the peak time (n*).62 We should also note
here the criticism by F.M. Bass: „one of the key outputs of the diffusion model is the
prediction of the timing and magnitude of the peak. Therefore, if one can guess these
items, there is no need to estimate model parameters.“ 63

Since we have already had a series of historical data about diffusion of consumer
durables under study, we can use the first three methods of estimation described above. We
beign with OLS method. The estimation results are summarized in Tab.3.

56
Mahajan, V., E. Muller and F.M.Bass, Op. cit., p. 6.
57
Mahajan, V. and Y. Wind „Innovation Diffusion Models of New Product Acceptance: A Reexamination“, in
Mahajan, V. and Y. Wind (eds.) „Innovation Diffusion Modes of New Product Acceptance“, N.Y., Ballinger,
1986, pp.3-25, p. 11.
58
Bass, F.M. Op. cit.
59
Schmittlein, D.C. and V. Mahajan, „Maximum Likelihood Estimation for An Innovation Diffusion Model of
New Product Acceptance“, Marketing Science, Vol. !, No. 1, Winter 1982, pp. 57-78.
60
Srinivasan, V. and C:H. Mason, „Nonlinear Least Squares Estimation of New Product Diffusion Models“,
Marketing Science, Vol. 5, No. 2, Spring,(1986), pp. 169-178.
61
Mahajan, V. and S. Sherma, „Simple Algebric Estimation Procedure for Innovation Diffusion Models of New
Product Acceptance“, Techonological Forecasting and Social Change, 30 (1986), pp. 331-46.
62
Mahajan, V., E. Muller and F.M.Bass, Op.cit., p. 8.

18
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

2
Tab. 3: Estimated Parameters' Values and R Values in Bass Model (OLS)
2
Product Basis p q m R
Name (Significant
Level)
Computer Ks. 0.0064 0.5884 316894 0.916
(0.00)
Computer Units 0.0086 0.8646 289367 0.834
(0.00)
Air- Ks. -2.45578E-08 0.4039 1,09783E+11 0.861
conditioner (0.00)
Air- Units -0.0019 0.5030 301219 0.831
conditioner (0.00)
TV Ks. 0.0142 -0.0036 4138681 0.253
(0.174)
TV Units 1.5169E-07 0.2090 1,02956E+11 0.431
(0.034)
Telephone Ks. -0.0497 0.8662 53144 0.552
(0.008)
Telephone Units 0.0490 0.3060 19870 0.019
(0.889)

When we look at the results, it has been found that the Bass model fits well with two
products, namely computer and air-conditioner (both volume and units), while it cannot
explain the diffusion process of the rest products, namely TV and telephone. This may be due
to the distinctive nature of original data as we have noticed in the diagrams. Even though the
model fits with the data of air-conditioner, the parameter values of p are given in minus sign.
Thus it must be said that the Bass model generates unplausible results in some products
diffused in developing country (Myanmar). Now again we can compare the parameter values
of our study with those in international study. Sultan et al. reported in their meta analysis of
15 diffusion studies, that the coefficient of innovation (p) averages 0.03 and the coefficient of
imitation (q) averages 0.38 but values vary very considerably.64 Compared with this, we can
find that the parameters of our study show different results beyond the internatioal range.
Particularly, the innovation coefficient p is much smaller than the international average of
0.03, while the coefficient of q is much greater than the international average of 0.38 (at least
in the case of computer).Hence, we can interpret that in developing countries the diffusion
process is mainly accelerated by the imitators rather than innovators in relation to developed
countries. As expected and agreed with theoretical point of view, we propose thereby that
developing countries are less innovative, however, they are more imitative than developed
countries. Moreover, our results support to the following hypothesis of Takada and Jain:

63
Mahajan, V., E. Muller and F.M.Bass, Op.cit., p. 8.
64
Sultan, F., J.U. Farley und D.R. Lehmann, „A Meta-Analysis of Applications of Diffusion Models“, Journal of
Marketing Research, 27b (1990), pp. 70-77, p. 71.

19
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

„The later a product is introduced in a market, the faster will be the rate of adoption.
Consequently, the imitation coefficient will have a larger for a country in which th product is
introduced later than for the country in which the product is first introduced.“65

In addition to the OLS estimation, we have also applied the nonlinear least square
(NLS) estimation method proposed by Srinivasan and Mason. In this method, the sales X(i) in
the ith time interval (ti-1, ti) is given by:66

X(i) = m[F(ti) – F(ti-1)] + ui

1 – e – (p+q) ti 1 – e –(p +q ) ti-1


X(i) = m [ ________________ _ __________________ ] + ui for i=1, 2, ....., T,
1 – (q/p) e- (p+q)q) ti 1 – (q/p) e –(p +q ) ti-1

where m = the number of eventual adopters

In OLS method the parameters p, q and m are not directly estimated and the regression
analog equation of the Bass model has been instead applied, we cannot obtain the signifiance
level and standard error of each parameter. Moreover, there can be some problems with
multicolinearity among input data, since the cummulative adoption at a time has been used
twice but in different orders.67 Using the nonlinear least squares (NLS) estimation, the
parameters are directly estimated and standard errors are also provided by using asymptotic
approximations.68

65
Takada, H. and D. Jain, Op. cit., p. 50.
66
Srinavasan V. and C. H. Mason, Op. cit., p. 170.
67
Mahajan, V. E. Muller and F.M. Bass; Op. cit. p. 9. See also Schmittlein, D.C. and V. Mahajan, Op. cit,
p. 59-60.
68
Srinivasan, V. and C.H. Mason, Op. cit. p.171

20
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

The following is the results estimated by NLS.


2
Tab. 4: Estimated Parameters' Values and R Values in Bass Model (NLS)
by Srinivasan and Mason(1986)
2
Product Name Basis p q m R
Computer Ks. 0.00114 0.41182 490309 0.96755
Computer Units 0.00025 0.58613 431500 0.89295
Air-conditioner Ks. 0.00006 0.69123 668256 0.92233
Air-conditioner Units 0.00058 0.44385 345763 0.87755
TV Ks. 0.15832 0.27926 1313059 0.32518
TV Units 0.10913 0.22211 1200694 0.44496
Telephone Ks*. 0.00004 0.75234 62534 0.61748
Telephone Units** 0.00018 1 17493 0.2681
* Constraint: p greater than or equal to 1
** Constraints: both p and q greater than or equal to 1

When we compare the results between the OLS and NLS estimation, it has been found
that NLS method produces higher levels of goodness of fit (R2) than OLS. Moreover, NLS
can produce plausible results (with proper direction of signs), because it is possible to set the
constraints like p > 0, q > 0. Nevertheless, the interpretation on parameters are not different
from that of OLS.

The Extended Bass Model


We will now estimate the parameters of the extended Bass model which is built to
apply in the setting of developing countries. The model as described earlier requires to
estimate four parameters: p, q, r and m. Since it is impossible to estimate by means of OLS,
we will use the nonlinear least square (NLS) estimation method available in the SPSS
software. We estimate, however, only three parameters, p, q and r; m is set according to the
value obtained in earlier estimation works. Here we take the values from NLS estimation by
Srinavasan and Mason. As explained in data, data for lead country (Japan) are available for
only two products, TV and telephone, hence we estimate the parameters of the extended Bass
model for these two products. Tab.5 shows the results of our estimation.

21
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

2
Tab. 5: Estimated Parameter Values and R Values in Extended Bass Model
by NLS*
2
Product Name Basis p q r R
TV Ks. 0 0.2585 0.0366 0.3484
TV Units 0 0.2095 0.0257 0.4102
Telephone Ks. 0 0.6832 -0.0579 0.5011
Telephone Units 0 0.4029 0.1211 0.0126
* Constraint: p greater than or equal to 1

When we look at the results, we find firstly that the parameter p’s values are changed
into 0: this is also due to imposing of the constraint p = 0 or p > 0. Without this constraint, p
values result in negative sign.69 In place of innovative coefficients, the parameter r
(coefficient of international imitation) enters into existence. But an unplausible minus sign
appears for telephone (Ks.). As a result of the existence of the influence of international
imitation (r), the coefficient q’s values become lower. When we look at the degree of
goodness of fit, the extended model can improve a little bit only in one case (TV –Ks.) and in
the other three cases the model’s degree of fitness has decreased.
At the next stage, we examine the lag effect of international diffusion i.e. the
saturation level in industrialized countries, here Japan. The results shown above are obtained
for the condition in which the international diffusion is perceived simultaneously by the
potential adopters in developing countries, here Myanmar. It means that there is no time lag (
= 0). We have tested the effect of varying time lag ( = 1, 2 and 5). on the parameter r and the
degree of goodness of fit (R2). These results are shown in the Tab. 6.
When we analyze the effects of time-lag in the perception of international diffusion by
potential adopters in developing countries, we find that the best fit comes from simultaneous
perception instead of time-lag. It can be also seen that the longer the time lag, the lesser is the
degree of goodness of fit as well as the value of parameter „r“. As there is a long time-lag and
consequently the coefficient of international imitation, paramter „r“ declines and the
coefficientof innovation or parameter p comes into existence again.

69
This condition is comparable with the estimation results of Ganesh and Kumar, Op. cit. p. 334-335. In their
study of diffusion of retail scanner, the coefficient p values were negative when the learning effect model was
applied.

22
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

Tab. 6: The Effect of Time-lag in perception of international Diffusion on Parameters and


Goodness of Fit
Product Type Base Time Lag ()
=0 =1 =2 = 5
TV Ks. p 0 0.0212 0.0212 0.0212
q 0.2585 0.2651 0.2651 0.2651
r 0.0366 0 0 0
2
R 0.3484 0.3467 0.3467 0.3467

TV Unit p 0 0 0.0151 0.0151


q 0.2095 0.2096 0.216 0.216
r 0.0257 0.026 0 0
2
R 0.4102 0.4098 0.4092 0,4092

Telephone Ks. p 0 0 0 0
q 0.6832 0.5564 0.5564 0.5564
r -0.0579 0 0 0
2
R 0.5011 0.4611 0.4611 0.4611

Television Unit p 0 0 0 0.0503


q 0.4029 0.4121 0.4197 0.4964
r 0.211 0.116 0.112 0
2
R 0.0126 0.0102 0.006 0.0048

Conclusion
Innovation diffusion is much interested by marketers, because this phenomenon can
explain how a new innovative product spreads in a market. As traditional domestic marketing
is expanded towards international marketing and global marketing, the application of innvatin
diffusion and its models go also beyond a single country, and the multiple countries become
the focus of the study. The international aspect of innovation diffusion has been widely
considered in 1990s. The international study of innovation diffusion comprises two kinds:
breadth and depth. Some studies attempted to link between countries applying the lead-lag
concept, while the others continued to study individual markets without such relationship. It
has been also found that the models used in the cross-nation studies include Bass-type models
and non-Bass type models.
Despite the increased interest in multinational aspects of innovation diffusion, no
emphasis on developing countries has been given. Some authors like Dekimpe et al. stress the
need to focus on developing countries with respect to innovation diffusion. It can be expected
that there are some differences between developed countries and developing countries. For

23
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

instance, the innovation diffusion in developing countries may be slower due to economic,
social and cultural factors, whereas it may be speedy due to time effect (together with
demonstration effect or learning effect generated by developed countries) and greater word-
of-mouth communication. Todays, as there are more and more developments in
communication and globalization emerges, however, we need to investigate thoroughly the
actual diffusion processes in developing countries.
We proposed a cross-nation diffusion model extending basic Bass-model. In the
literature, we found that our proposed model is very similar to that of Ganesh and Kumar who
studied the industrail technology diffusion. In our model, we add a new type of coefficient
which reflects the behaviour of international imitation into the adoption rate of a period. Thjs
model is appropriate for developing countries, because the consumers there orient towards the
consumption in developed countries: this kind of behaviour is obviously seen in a particular
segment of elite consumers. We termed the resulting effect as international demonstration
effect rather than learning effect. By this way, our proposed extended model is in agreement
with theorectical behavioural premises. We tested the soundness of our model with empircal
data.
We used the data of innovation diffusion for some consumer durables from two
countries: Myanmar and Japan. Myanmar plays the role of developing countries and Japan for
developed countries. So Japan is a lead country and Myanmar is a lag country. We firstly
tested the appropriateness of Bass model by estimating parameters. Out of four products
(computer, air-conditioner, TV set and telephone), only the first two products showed a high
degree of goodness of fit. By this point, we like to conclude that Bass model cannot be always
applicable when innovatin diffusion in developing countries is investigated. The reason
behind this is that in developing countries, many factors can influence in the diffusion
process. For example, government policy and restrictions, political situation, trade
relationships, infrastructure, etc. may be imposing the constraints upon free process of
diffusion. Compared to this, developed countries may have negligible restrictions and
constraints. In our Myanamr data, we can obviously see the irregularities in yearly adoption
amounts in telephone. Under such conditions, the Bass model will not function well.
When we studied the parameter values, the results were as we expected. The parameter
of innovation or external influence (p) is very small and the parameter of imitation or internal
influence (q) is considerably large. It can be even said that the adoption behaviour in
developing countries is shaped solely by imitators. In the parameter estimation, we applied
two methods, ordinary least square (OLS) and nonlinear least square (NLS). NLS is clearly

24
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

better than OLS in terms of degree of goodness of fit (R2) values. We found also that using
Bass model estimated by OLS had produced in some cases unplausible results, especially the
wrong sign.
When we tested the soundness of the extended Bass model which is particularly built
for developing countries, the results were not decisive. Due to unavailablity of data of the
lead-country (Japan) in some consumer durables, namely computer and air-conditioner, we
could only test in two products which data originally do not show typical diffusion patterns.
Out of our estimatin work, we could find however the existence of influence of internatinal
imitation. The parameter ( r ) was determined in all cases, except that there was a case with
negative sign. Another finding is that the innovation coefficient (p) was no more in existence
as the new parameter ( r ) entered. Thus, we like to propose that the diffusion process in
developing countries is merely the imitation process (comprising conventional imitation and
international imitation) without any effect of innovative behaviour. This finding is very
plausible in the context of developing countries. We cannot, however, conclude firmly this
pattern because we found that the extended model could not improve the goodness of fit
except in one case and the extent of improvement is not significant. Actually we need to study
further and collect findings in order to make sound conclusion about this peculiar pattern.
We have studied also the effect of time-lag in the perception of internatinal diffusion.
We entered the degree of international diffusion differently with time-lag 1, 2 and 5, we found
that the best fit occurs when there is a simultaneous perception without delay. As there is a
time-lag or delay, the model’s abiltiy to fit with actual data declines. The parameter of
international diffusion becomes also smaller and smaller till it reaches zero. Again the
innovation coefficient (p) appears and exits, as the parameter of international imitation
disappears due to time-lag.
By looking these results, we like to conclude that the extended model has a good
potential to be used in the setting of developing countries, although the model cannot
guarantee its soundness. It is probable that the model’s usefulness depends on the particular
case. Thus, we need to contiume to test the model with many atual data. Here we can propose
to study a theoretical aspect of innovation diffusion in developing countries, whether there
exists innovation inflence or international imitation influence. So we raise a question about
the dilemma of innovator vs. international imitator in developing countries. The
comprehensive scale of study in developing countries about the diffusion process to be
conducted in the future will answer this.

25
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

References

Bass, F. M. „A New Product Growth Model for Consumer Durables“, Management Science,
15(1969), pp. 215-2127.
Dekimpe, M.G., P.M. Parker and M. Sarvary, „Comparing Adoption Patterns: A Global Approach“, Working
Paper (96/37/MKT), INSEAD; 1996.
--------------------------------------------------------------„Globalization: Modeling technology adoption timing across
countries“, Working Paper (96/38/MKT), INSEAD, 1996.
---------------------------------------------------------------„Global Diffusion of Network Technologies: A Double-Hazard
Approach“, Working Paper (97/50/MKT), INSEAD, 1997.
-------------------------------------------------------------- „Multi-Market and Global Diffusion“, Working Paper, INSEAD,
1998.
Eliashberg, J.and K. Helsen, „Cross-country Diffusion Processes and Market Entry Timing“, Working Paper,
University of Pennsylvania, 1987.
Eliashberg,, J. and K. Helsen, „Modeling lead/lag Phenomena in Global Marketing: The case of VCRs“,
Working Paper, University of Pennsylvania, 1996
Ganesh, J. and V. Kumar, „Capturing the Cross-national Learning Effect: An Analysis of an Industrial
Technology Diffusion“, Journal of the Academy of Marketing Research, 24
(1996), pp. 328-337.
Ganesh, J., V. Kumar and V. Subramaniam, „Learning Effect in Multinational Diffusion of Consumer Durables:
An Exploratory Investigation“, Journal of the Academy of
Marketing Science, 25 (1997), pp. 214-228.
Gatignon, H. and T.S. Robertson, „ A propositional Inventory for New Diffusifon Research“, Journal of
Consumer Research, Vol. 11, March 1985, pp. 849-867.
Gatignon, H., J. Eliasherrg and T.S. Robertson, „Modeling Multinational Difusion Patterns: An Efficient
Methodology“, Journal of Management Science, Vol. 8, No.
3, Summer 1989, pp. 231- 246.
Heller, R. M. and T.P. Hustad „Problems in predicting New Product growth for Consumer Durables“,
Management Science, 26 (1980), pp. 1007-1020. .
Helsen, K. K. Jedidi, K. and W.S. DeSarbo, „A New Approach to Country Segmentation utilizing
Multinational Diffusion Patterns“, Journal of Marketing,
57(1993), pp. 60-71..
Mahajan, V., E. Muller and S. Kalish, „Waterfall and Sprinkler New-Product Strategies in Competitive Global
Markets“, Working Paper, University of Texas at Austin, 1990
Mahajan, V. and E. Muller, „Innovation Diffusion in a Borderless Global Market: Will the 1992 Unification of
the European Community Accelerate Difuusion of New Ideas, Products and
Technologies“, Technological Forecasting and Soical Change, 45, (1994),
pp. 221-237.
Mahajan, V. and S. Sherma, „Simple Algebric Estimation Procedure for Innovation Diffusion Models of New
Product Acceptance“, Techonological Forecasting and Social Change, 30
(1986), pp. 331-46.
Mahajan, V. and Y. Wind „Innovation Diffusion Models of New Product Acceptance: A Reexamination“, in
Mahajan, V. and Y. Wind (eds.) „Innovation Diffusion Modes of New Product Acceptance“, N.Y., Ballinger,
1986, pp.3-25.
Mahajan, V. E. Muller and F.M. Bass, „New Product Diffusion Models in Marketing: A Review and
Directions for Research“, Journal of Marketing, 54(1990),
pp. 1-26.
Mahajan, V. and M:E.F. Schoeman, „Generalized Model for the Time Pattern of the Diffusiom Process“,
IEEE Transactions on Enginerring Management, Feb. 1977,
pp. 12-18.
Min, Sein „Exportmarketing im Wirtschaftsverkehr zwischen Industrie- und Entwicklungsländern: Eine
computer gestützte Simulationsanalyze zur Ermiitlung optimaler Strategien für die
abzatzpolitischen Instrumente“, Dissertation, Universität Passau, 1990.
Peterson, R. A. and V. Mahajan, „Multi-Product Growth Models“, in „Research in Marketing“ ed. Jagdish
Sheth, Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, 1978.
Rogers, M. „Diffusion of Innovations“, New York , The Free Press, 1995.
Sartorious, B. „Exportmarkeing ffür neuartige Gebrauchsgüter auf verbundenen Märkten“, Dissertation,
Universität Passau, 1983.
Schmalen, H. „Marketing-Mix für neuartige Gebrauchsgüter“, Gabler, Wiesbaden, 1979.

26
Innovation Diffusion in Developing Countries

Schmalen, H. „Das Bass-Modell zur Diffusionsforschung: Darstellung, Kritik und Modifikation“, ZfbF, 1989,
pp.1191-1209.
Schnmlen, H. and H. Xander, „Produkteinführung und Diffusion“, in S. Albers and A. Hermann (ed.),
“Handbuch Produktmanagement: Strategieenwicklung – Produktplanung –
Organisation – Kontrolle“, Gabler, 2000.
Schmittlein, D.C. and V. Mahajan, „Maximum Likelihood Estimation for An Innovation Diffusion Model of
New Product Acceptance“, Marketing Science, Vol. !, No. 1, Winter
1982, pp. 57-78.
Srinivasan, V. and C:H. Mason, „Nonlinear Least Squares Estimation of New Product Diffusion Models“,
Marketing Science, Vol. 5, No. 2, Spring,(1986), pp. 169-178.
Takada, H. and D. Jain, „Cross National Analysis of Diffusion of Consumer Durable Goods in Pacific Rim
Countries“, Journal of Marketing, 55 (1991), pp. 48-54.
Tanny, S.M. and N. A. Derzko, „Innovators and Imitators in Innovation Diffusion Modelling“, Journal of
Forecasting, Vol. 7, 1988, pp. 225-234.
United Nation, „Statistical Yearbook“, various issues.
Vernon, R. „International Investment and International Trade in the Product Cycle“, in: Quarterly Journal of
Economics, Vol. 80, No. 2, (May 1966), pp. 190-207.
Wells, L.T.Jr. „International Trade: The Product Life Cycle Approach“, in: Wells, L.T.Jr. (ed.) „the Product
Life Cycle and International Trade“, Boston, 1972.

27

You might also like